Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes

Home > Other > Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes > Page 24
Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes Page 24

by Democracy in Dangerous Places (pdf)


  be states. The problem of being too small is, if anything, even more daunting than the problem of being too large. If a continent is divided into a patchwork of tiny countries each too small to have in-

  ternalized the key externalities, vital public goods will be missing.

  Even for basics, such as the generation of electricity and the provi-

  sion of road and rail networks, in a patchwork of small territories

  the public goods are regional rather than merely national. The radi-

  cally larger scale of territory of the colonial empires is one reason

  that their infrastructure decisions were manifestly superior to those

  of the post-independence governments: Africa is still relying on

  their faded legacy.

  Better Dead Than Fed?

  191

  To get specific, Central Africa has ideal geography for hydro-

  electric power: high rainfall over a massive area of high ground that

  collects into the River Congo. The descent to sea level could generate

  power for much of Africa and has been a development project for

  decades. The project has barely moved. The Democratic Republic of

  the Congo does not itself need all that power, while other countries

  are not willing to put themselves at the mercy of its president, or,

  for that matter, at the mercy of the presidents of any of the countries

  that power lines might have to traverse. The excess of national sov-

  ereignty possessed by these presidents has delivered power shortages

  across the region. As a huge landmass Africa is also well suited to

  railways. Many were built by the colonizing powers. Try traveling

  on them now: there is an acute shortage of rolling stock. It should be

  easy to finance new rolling stock: elsewhere a rail company can raise

  finance by pledging the stock itself as collateral, much as you can

  buy an auto on credit. But the rolling stock cannot be accepted as

  collateral because it might roll away over a national frontier. There

  is so little neighborhood cooperation in law enforcement that once it

  is across the border it might as well have been taken to Mars.

  So small is ugly as far as public goods are concerned. Being

  small artificially limits the benefits of state provision, and this ac-

  centuates the lack of supply: the lower the payoff, the weaker the

  incentive to try.

  P ot e n t i a l ly t h e s tat e s o f t h e bottom billion could themselves cooperate to supply the public goods that cannot be supplied

  at the level of each state. Indeed, to the extent that they cannot ef-

  ficiently be supplied because they are regional public goods, there is

  an incentive to cooperate. Regional cooperation is the least invasive

  challenge to national sovereignty, and so if it is feasible, it is at this

  level that international supply of accountability and security should

  be undertaken. Is it feasible?

  192

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  Since the societies of the bottom billion are radically less able

  to supply the key public goods at the level of each state than are

  other societies, it might be expected that they would rely more

  than other societies upon cooperation. They have much more to

  gain than the larger and more homogenous high-income coun-

  tries. Among the high-income countries themselves this is indeed

  the clear pattern: the two countries that have been least interested

  in pooling sovereignty are the two largest, America and Japan.

  The country that has been most enthusiastic, indeed providing the

  home for the European Community, has been the small and di-

  verse society of Belgium. I almost forgot Luxembourg, which is

  equally keen. Among the plethora of countries that emerged from

  the collapse of the Soviet Union, the small countries have queued

  up to pool their sovereignty into the European Union, whereas

  Russia has held itself aloof.

  Accepting these understandable differences in the degree of

  enthusiasm, over the past half century the developed nations have

  started to get the hang of how to cooperate, albeit fitfully. Gradually,

  sovereignty is being pooled where there are clear advantages. The

  most dramatic pooling of sovereignty occurred earlier: the shift to-

  ward federal power within the United States. Fifty states, nearly all of which have economies far larger than the typical economy of the bottom billion, have learned how to cooperate. The next most dramatic

  is the European Community: twenty-seven states have pooled some

  sovereignty, although much less than in the United States. At an-

  other layer down, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and

  Development is a grouping of thirty high-income countries that has

  built up a long tradition of mutual reinforcement of governance.

  Even the middle-income countries have no equivalent to the

  sovereignty pooling of the high-income countries. The Asian tsu-

  nami was so devastating because the countries bordering the Indian

  Ocean had not got around to cooperating on an earthquake-warn-

  ing system. In the bottom billion the lack of cooperation is more

  Better Dead Than Fed?

  193

  pronounced. There are many regional groupings of these countries

  but they do not effectively bind their members: they are essentially

  decorative.

  To see the contrasting trends, compare Germany, the largest

  country in Europe, with Burundi, one of the smallest countries in

  Africa. Both countries have a troubled past and have been a men-

  ace to the neighborhood, but think how their degree of sovereignty

  now differs. One of them does not have its own currency, does not

  control its own interest rate, does not control its own trade policy,

  is subject to rules that limit its budget deficit, can have decisions in

  its courts overruled by decisions in courts run by the neighborhood,

  and cannot prevent foreign companies from taking over its firms.

  The other country has total sovereignty over all these matters. The

  country with the more limited sovereignty is Germany: yet the Ger-

  man economy is thirty-two hundred times the size of the Burundi

  economy. If we apply the concept of internalizing externalities, Bu-

  rundi should be pooling its sovereignty with its neighbors far more

  vigorously than Germany. Generally, small countries need to pool

  more sovereignty than large countries. Everyone other than Ameri-

  cans gets upset that America often refuses to pool its sovereignty, but

  as the largest economy in the world America has least need to do so:

  it has already internalized a huge array of externalities by pooling

  sovereignty within its borders. The paradox is that despite having

  the most to gain from pooling their sovereignty, the societies of the

  bottom billion have pooled it the least.

  Return, for a moment, to those externalities that each country

  of the bottom billion has on others. Sometimes these externalities are

  reciprocal, so that if two countries cooperate they both benefit. These

  are the easy public goods to supply through regional cooperation.

  If everyone benefits, then cooperation should be feasible, although

  even here the record is not encouraging. But often the externalities

 
are not reciprocal. Quite commonly, in the absence of cooperation,

  although one country suffers a lot from adverse externalities, the

  194

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  other country gains a little. If I were to write through the night to

  music, it would help me a little but my family would not be able to

  sleep. In a family it is easy to internalize that externality: I write in

  silence. But if Kenya were to fix the road to Uganda and commit

  to keeping it open, something that would help landlocked Uganda

  enormously, it would cost Kenya a little money and Kenya would

  have to sacrifice some political leverage. These public goods are un-

  likely to be supplied by cooperation. In principle, economics has the

  solution to such situations: the government of Uganda should offer

  sufficient financial compensation to the government of Kenya that

  cooperation is in the interests of both countries. It doesn’t happen

  and it is not going to happen: the road linking Uganda to the coast

  has been unreliable ever since Kenya’s independence. Or take the

  new iron ore discovery in Guinea. Fortuitously, an existing colonial

  railway links the site to a nearby port, Buchanan. But unfortunately,

  Buchanan is in Liberia, so instead a new railway is to be constructed

  and a new port built. The new route will be much longer, but it will

  stay within Guinea. More than half of the $6 billion cost of the new

  mine is due to this decision: the extra cost about equals the national

  income of Liberia. For those externalities that are not reciprocal,

  regional cooperation is ruled out, and so the only option is to inter-

  nalize them at a higher-level international cooperation.

  This is by no means the only problem faced by regional cooper-

  ation. Consider specifically the provision of the missing public good

  of accountability. African states are indeed currently cooperating to

  provide a degree of mutual scrutiny through the African Peer Re-

  view Mechanism. This is a new arrangement whereby governments

  can volunteer to be assessed by other governments. I strongly support

  it, but to date African governments have shown no stomach for such

  criticism. Indeed, such an approach faces enormous difficulties. If,

  within their own societies, none of the component governments is

  individually accountable, a club to provide accountability regionally

  faces two acute problems: legitimacy and incentives. The legitimacy

  Better Dead Than Fed?

  195

  problem is that the first government to be criticized can turn around

  and say, quite reasonably, “So the pot is calling the kettle black!”

  The incentive problem is that interstate cooperation largely

  means inter government cooperation. But why should governments

  that are not accountable cooperate to build restraints upon them-

  selves? Even if some governments are sufficiently farsighted to see

  some gains from such restraints, cooperation can usually be blocked

  by a few stubborn participants. Take the recent collapse of account-

  ability in Zimbabwe. If ever there is going to be a need for account-

  ability to be reinforced by the neighborhood, this is it. To his credit,

  in 2007 President Mwanawasa of neighboring Zambia indeed tried

  to raise concerns about the meltdown in Zimbabwe at a meeting

  of the presidents of southern Africa. With several million Zimba-

  bweans fleeing the country his concern was understandable. But

  President Mwanawasa received little support from other presidents.

  Indeed, the report comparing economic performance that had been

  prepared for the meeting was not even presented, lest it cause em-

  barrassment. Mugabe himself stormed out of the meeting as though

  the very expression of concern was an outrage: why should he not

  ruin his country if he wanted to do so? Indeed, African presidents

  have generally rallied around President Mugabe. Far from criticiz-

  ing him they elected Zimbabwe to the chair of the United Nations

  Human Rights Committee. Even when Mugabe tried to import a

  huge arms shipment, it took a strike by South African dockers to

  block it. Mugabe could only have wanted the guns either to crush

  the opposition or to menace his neighbors, yet without those dock-

  ers, neighboring governments would have remained passive.

  A final problem is that just as leadership matters in forging a

  nation out of its distinct ethnic groups, so leadership matters in gal-

  vanizing a group of countries into meaningful collective action. The

  European Union did not just happen: it took the vision of commit-

  ted leaders who saw that the long-term interests of their country

  would be enhanced by pooling some sovereignty. So it is the respon-

  196

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  sibility of the national leaders within the political groupings of the

  countries of the bottom billion to build cooperation. In recent years

  they have been rather short of visionary and charismatic regional

  leadership. The last time Africa had such leadership was in the early

  post-independence phase when Presidents Nkrumah of Ghana and

  Nyerere of Tanzania promoted an agenda of Pan-Africanism. The

  actual content was a prisoner of its time: the agenda of unity against

  the Western world. But Pan-Africanism failed not primarily because

  of this content, but because forging any unity of purpose among so

  many countries is difficult.

  I f s ov e r e i g n s tat e s a r e t o o small, yet regional cooperation between them is too difficult, one radical alternative is to federate

  them into a few larger states. This is the route that America took,

  and it was briefly tried in late colonial Africa. A straightforward

  obstacle to merging states is that certain personnel would become

  redundant, and like all about-to-be-made-redundant employees,

  they might object. If two states merge they need only one president,

  one set of ministers, one army. Perhaps that is why state mergers are

  so rare.

  While the perks of high office might account for the reluctance

  of states to merge, there is a deeper question: would it alleviate or in-

  tensify the key weakness of small size, the inability to reap the scale

  economies of security. However, recall that unfortunately there are

  two opposing effects of an increase in size on insecurity, not just the

  benefits of greater scale but the increased risk associated with any

  consequential reduction in cohesion. But would state merger fur-

  ther worsen the lack of cohesion? It is quite possible that given the

  arbitrary nature of colonial boundaries, with straight lines carving

  through societies, some mergers would not increase ethnic diversity.

  Even if it did, the security gains from scale might outweigh the dan-

  gers of increased diversity.

  Better Dead Than Fed?

  197

  This is a question that is just about researchable. Christian Wig-

  strom, a Swedish graduate student at Oxford, got interested, and we

  decided to investigate it. We decided to replay the decolonization

  process, imagining the consequences had Africa been packaged into

  fewer
countries. Rather than redraw boundaries, we decided to pro-

  gressively rub them off the map, first merging countries into pairs,

  and continuing the merger process until we reached the African

  dream of a politically united sub-Saharan Africa. You may variously

  view this as social science gone mad; as an arrogant attempt to play

  God with countries; or as something that might conceivably inform

  the political impetus within Africa to break beyond the colonially

  imposed mosaic and achieve greater unity.

  One of the most exhilarating consequences of building a model

  is that it enables the researcher to simulate alternative scenarios. We

  had to establish some principle to guide the merger sequence: for

  example, should Kenya first merge with Uganda or with Tanzania?

  We decided that our guiding criterion would be to minimize the

  risks facing the merged state, so we looked for states with similar

  ethnic composition. In effect, these were hypothetical marriages of

  countries that were as ethnically similar as possible. In the process

  we discovered that because the boundaries of the old empires often

  sliced through ethnic groups, it was sometimes possible to make na-

  tions bigger without making them more diverse. On our analysis

  such nations would have been more secure: they would have gained

  from scale economies without losing from additional diversity. We

  also found that state boundaries at least appear to have been drawn

  as attempts to trade off scale against diversity. In places where there

  was atypically high ethnic diversity, the states were also unusually

  small. It is these states, small yet diverse, that face the most severe

  problems of internal security. As the hypothetically merged nations

  gradually came out of this process, we then estimated their risks of

  violence from the simulation model that I had built with Anke and

  Dominic. We could address, at least after a fashion, the question of

  198

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  how badly wrong the decolonization process had been in their pack-

  aging decisions from the perspective of security.

  Our somewhat eccentric research is still in progress, but it looks

  as though Africa’s multitude of ethnic groups could have been bun-

  dled up into around seven large states with little increase in ethnic

  diversity. A seven-state structure for Africa would, on our analy-

 

‹ Prev