Sixth Century BCE to Seventeenth Century

Home > Other > Sixth Century BCE to Seventeenth Century > Page 51
Sixth Century BCE to Seventeenth Century Page 51

by Ying-shih Yü


  by the local government with a stone stele because he had single- handedly taken

  care of the vast expenses for the construction, near his hometown, of a huge

  stone bridge and a long road dotted with pavilions for travelers’ rest. Greatly

  excited by the grandeur and glory this gigantic proj ect had brought to their

  town, local residents remarked: “It is quite enough to be a merchant. Why

  should anyone care to be a scholar?” From a diff er ent perspective, his son- in-

  law, a scholar himself, also commented, “A well- groomed scholar can indeed

  discourse a great deal on abstract princi ples, but he could do little to help other

  people. My father- in- law has done enormously for others. What’s the point for

  him to become a scholar?”141 As these two cases clearly show, what Shen Yao

  called “the philanthropic spirit of the merchants” had, over time, brought them

  broader and more lasting recognition from both state and society. From this

  time on, the entire social atmosphere seemed to be changing slowly but steadily

  in the merchants’ favor. It was by no means unrealistic to say that a late Ming

  merchant could feel that a life wholly devoted to business was a life worth living.

  With merchants and scholars being increasingly undiff erentiated, they not only

  came to share more of the old values but also developed new values together. As

  I have shown elsewhere, interpenetration between business culture and elite

  culture was not a one- way traffi

  c with the merchant always imitating the scholar.

  It worked in reverse as well.142

  Before closing, I wish to take a quick look at the business culture of the

  Ming- Qing Period and its relations to Chinese traditions. Due to space limita-

  tions, I can do no more than make a few brief comments.

  First, the new business culture. A term that we often encounter in the bio-

  graphical lit er a ture on merchants of this period is gudao

  (“merchant way” or

  “way of business”). Its meaning seems to vary from one context to another. How-

  ever, in one par tic u lar sense, it is clearly a reference to certain market laws that

  one must follow to make his business a success. I shall discuss the term only in

  this technical sense. Kang Hai

  (1475–1541), a famous writer from Shaanxi,

  reported a criticism his deceased uncle made of a merchant who waited for

  prices to go up before selling his commodities. It runs as follows: “He does not

  understand the way of business ( gudao). To wait for a fi xed price before selling is

  the way of the mediocre trader who seeks to avoid loss, but who can pass a whole

  year without making a single transaction. Those who do as I do can eff ect more

  than ten transactions a year, and so can make more than ten times the profi t the

  mediocre merchant can manage.”143 What is particularly in ter est ing in this pas-

  sage is that the critic seems to have rediscovered the princi ple fi rst enunciated

  by Jiran in the fi fth century b.c.e. that “one should not risk a merchandise for

  busine s s c ul t ur e a nd c h ine s e t r adi t ions 257

  high prices to come,” as quoted earlier. Throughout the sixteenth and seven-

  teenth centuries, scholars’ writings on the merchants are pervasively infi ltrated

  with the language of Sima Qian’s

  chapter on “Money- Makers.” This was

  obviously the inevitable result of the literary fashion of the day, which looked up

  to the Grand Historian of Han as the model prose writer. So what I just referred

  to as “rediscovery” of the pre- unifi cation ideas about the market may well have

  been a linguistic illusion. There is another possibility, however: it was the extra-

  linguistic real ity that invited the use of the specifi c language in question. What

  the merchants of the day did and said prob ably reminded these writers of the

  pre- unifi cation “money- makers.” What ever the case may be, it is impor tant to

  point out that Ming- Qing merchants developed market rationality to a much

  higher level than their pre- Qin pre de ces sors.

  I shall mention only two features in the Ming- Qing “way of business,”

  namely, the application of arithmetic to commerce and the emergence of “the

  princi ple of low prices and large turnover.” Both features happen to be taken by

  Max Weber as illustrative examples of “the pro cess of rationalization” in the

  rise of Western capitalism.144 I am not suggesting that Ming- Qing China devel-

  oped anything even remotely resembling “capitalism,” however. I agree with

  Weber that capitalism is a peculiar Western system. All I am saying is simply

  that these two features, central to the Chinese “way of business” in the Ming-

  Qing Period, fi t in well with Weber’s defi nition of rationality. There is no rea-

  son to assume that rationality, even market rationality, must of necessity lead to

  capitalism of the Western type.

  We have already quoted Wang Daokun that Huizhou people were more in-

  terested in arithmetic than the Confucian classics. This general statement can

  be amply substantiated. Cheng Dawei’s

  (1533–1606) Suanfa tongzong

  (General Compilation of Arithmetic), completed in 1593, was a fa-

  mous textbook on arithmetic designed specifi cally to give solutions to prob lems

  by means of the abacus. It was clearly intended to apply to business calculations

  due to the author’s early background as a merchant.145 Another example from

  Huizhou was Wang Tingbang

  (1729–1803), who also turned from a mer-

  chant to mathematician.146 Commercial arithmetic was so popu lar in Huizhou

  that even a house wife learned it in order to help her husband’s business book-

  keeping.147 But enthusiasm for commercial arithmetic was a nationwide phe-

  nomenon, not confi ned to Huizhou. Some late Ming commercial handbooks also

  devoted sections to it for the con ve nience of traveling merchants.148 While there

  was admittedly no double- entry bookkeeping in China, the commercial arithme-

  tic of the sixteenth century was nevertheless sophisticated enough to be compa-

  rable to its con temporary counterpart in Eu rope.149 In this connection, I may also

  mention that in merchant biographies of this period, the term “ mental calcula-

  tion” ( xinji

  ) is often emphasized as a desirable quality. A typically “fi ne mer-

  chant” is described as someone whose calculations are so precise that he will

  258 busine s s c ul t ur e a nd c h ine s e t r adi t ions

  neither make the slightest error nor miss a single opportunity.150 This is instru-

  mental rationality idealized to its highest pos si ble degree without that term.

  The princi ple of low prices and large turnover was also universally accepted

  and widely practiced in the Ming- Qing market. As a matter of fact, it is already

  implied in the above quoted remark of Kang Hai’s uncle about the “way of busi-

  ness.” The following anecdote is more revealing, however. According to Gu

  Xiancheng

  (1550–1612), the radical thinker He Xinyin

  (1517–1579)

  was once asked for advice by a young man on his way to becoming a merchant.

  He Xinyan gave him two formulas. The fi rst one was in six words: “buy one


  bit; sell one bit.” The second one was in four words: “buy wholesale; sell retail.”

  Following He’s advice, the young merchant made a fast fortune in the mar-

  ket.151 The story cannot be verifi ed, but whoever said them had a profound un-

  derstanding of the market economy, indeed. In eff ect, what the fi rst formula

  meant is to sell quickly what one has bought, which is almost identical with

  Weber’s princi ple. Now let me cite two examples to show that the princi ple

  was continually practiced by merchants with good business sense through the

  Ming- Qing Period. Jin Runai

  (1596–1645), a merchant from the Suzhou

  region, is described as follows: “While other merchants preferred to detain

  market commodities and wait for prices to soar before releasing them, Jin al-

  ways sold them at a lower price, passing on what he had bought in and discharg-

  ing what he had stored up, his objective being that his commodities should not

  be left unsold.”152 The other example was Tao Zhengxiang

  (1732–1797), a

  book dealer of Suzhou. According to Sun Xingyan

  (1753–1818), Mr. Tao

  once told a friend about his way of doing business thus: “Since I like profi t, I

  shall also let the purchasers of my books get their share of profi t. After all, who

  does not desire profi t as much as I do? If I try to monopolize the profi t so that

  the goods remain stagnant rather than circulating, this means losing the

  profi t altogether.” But Mr. Tao was not the only one who had a fi rm grasp of this

  princi ple. Sun Xingyan also knew two other merchants in the capital, art dealer

  Wang and antique dealer Gu, who held exactly the same view as Tao’s. All three

  fl ourished at the time.153

  Taking these two central features together, I think it is reasonable to suggest

  that the Chinese business world also underwent a “pro cess of rationalization”

  between 1500 and 1800. In the Chinese case, however, this pro cess was linked,

  not to capitalism, but to a more advanced market economy, to follow the distinc-

  tion made by Braudel.

  Second, the “way of business,” discussed above, may be regarded as the

  nucleus of Ming- Qing business culture. The concept of business culture is ex-

  tremely broad, however. If understood as a way of life associated with the busi-

  ness world, then we must say that business culture in the Ming- Qing times

  was practically coextensive with Chinese culture itself, for it touched every part

  of the Chinese tradition. A simple and easy way to explain this situation is to

  use a commercial handbook as an illustration, for such works were all compiled

  busine s s c ul t ur e a nd c h ine s e t r adi t ions 259

  by merchants. Take the Shishang leiyao

  (Classifi ed Essentials for

  Scholars and Merchants), dated 1626, as an example. It consists of four chap-

  ters ( juan

  ) . Chapter 1 is a travel guide including commercial routes. Chap-

  ter 2 is really the core, for it tells the merchant every thing he needs to know

  about the business world. More in ter est ing to note is that it contains popu lar-

  ized versions of general princi ples about the “way of business,” such as a rhymed

  prose on “trade” and an essay on “business management.” In the last two chap-

  ters, however, we fi nd “essentials” of every impor tant aspect of the Chinese world,

  past and pres ent. The topics range from history, cosmology, ethics, and religion

  to social relations, medicine, and po liti cal institutions. As its title clearly indi-

  cates, the handbook was designed to meet the needs of both traveling merchants

  and examination candidates in their everyday life. This is a concrete example

  showing how the social intermingling of merchants with scholars inevitably led

  to the interpenetration of culture between them.

  In this connection, let me also give a most amusing example to show that

  when our merchant- author laid his hand on something in the elite culture, he

  sometimes also changed it by way of reinterpretation. In a section on “Basic

  Guidelines for the Traveling Merchant,” the author discussed price mechanism

  in the market and quoted the Daodejing to support it. The quoted sentence says:

  “One who desires dear [goods] must have cheap [goods] as his root; one who

  desires high [prices] must take the opportunity when [prices] are low.”154 In the

  original text of the Laozi, however, it reads, “the humble is the stem upon which

  the mighty grows; the low is the foundation upon which the high is laid”

  (chap. 39). What ever it means, it speaks to “princes” and “barons” about their

  power base, having nothing to do with the market. Here our merchant- author

  not only quoted it completely out of context but also distorted its meaning

  through whimsical emendations, such as adding “one who desires” and changing

  “foundation” ( ji

  ) to “opportunity,” which happens to be a homophone ( ji

  ).

  This concrete case serves well as an illustration of the fact that by actively par-

  ticipating in the culture of the scholar, the merchant also transformed it.

  The imprint of business culture on the Chinese tradition was not spread

  evenly everywhere, however. It was more deeply felt in some areas than others.

  As we all know, its infl uences on the developments of popu lar religion and

  popu lar lit er a ture in the late Ming were enormous. Merchants of this period

  were generally very religious, and one of them, Cheng Yunzhang

  (1602–

  1651), even became the founder of a popu lar sect on the model of the Three-

  Teachings- in- One of Lin Zhao-en

  (1517–1598).155 There is also evidence

  that the so- called morality books ( shanshu

  ), a type of semireligious tract that

  gained widespread popularity in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, made

  special eff orts to encourage merchants to be generous with their money for

  charities and public works.156 On the other hand, fi ction, drama, and oral lit er a-

  ture not only created tremendous profi t for merchants in the book market157 but

  also provided other merchants with their most favorite reading materials. As an

  260 busine s s c ul t ur e a nd c h ine s e t r adi t ions

  early nineteenth- century Huizhou merchant remarked, “Merchants invariably

  turn to romances and novels as their pastimes,”158 but this reading habit had

  already begun as early as the fi fteenth century.159 For the sixteenth century, I

  can cite the remarkable example of Gu Xue

  , the merchant- father of Gu

  Xiancheng. In his early years, he was an avid reader of novels, especially the

  Shuihu zhuan

  ( Water Margin), and late in life, he became an enthusias-

  tic follower of Lin Zhao- en’s Three- Teachings- in- One sect.160 This example is

  remarkable because it kills two birds with one stone, showing beyond dispute

  the pivotal role of the merchant class in the promotion of popu lar lit er a ture and

  popu lar religion in Ming- Qing China.

  Fi nally, allow me to conclude by making an observation on the re orientation

  of the Confucian tradition in the Ming- Qing Period. Generally speaking, it

  seemed to exhibit a te
ndency toward relaxation of moral absolutism. Polarities

  such as “princi ple versus desire,” “common good versus self- interest,” “righ-

  teousness versus profi tableness,” “frugality versus luxury,” etc., had long been

  understood as opposites with the fi rst part (“princi ple,” “common good,” “righ-

  teousness,” and “frugality”) identifi ed as positive values and the second part (“de-

  sire,” “self- interest,” “profi tableness,” and “luxury”) as negative ones. From the

  sixteenth century on, however, many Confucian scholars and thinkers tended to

  reinterpret them as mutually complementary rather than mutually exclusive.

  What is more impor tant is that “desire,” “self- interest,” “profi tableness,” and “lux-

  ury” were all given a positive revaluation to a greater or lesser extent. It is impos-

  sible to trace the evolutionary pro cesses of these ideas here. Based on my previous

  research, I shall summarize my fi ndings on three of them whose relationship to

  business culture can be established on clear evidence.

  Self- interest. In the postclassical Confucian tradition, it was a generally ac-

  cepted princi ple that self- interest ( si

  ) must at all times be subordinate to

  common good ( gong

  ), which was predicated on the more fundamental

  princi ple of the priority of community to individual. Now suddenly, during the

  Ming- Qing transition, this received view was being seriously questioned. Each

  in his own way, Li Zhi

  (1527–1602), Chen Que

  (1604–1677), Huang

  Zongxi

  (1610–1695), Gu Yanwu

  (1613–1682) and, later, Dai Zhen

  (1724–1777) and Gong Zizhen

  (1792–1841) all proposed revisions as

  regards the relationship between gong and si. In the interest of simplicity, allow

  me to take Gu Yanwu’s neat formulation as representative of this new line of

  thinking. It runs as follows:

  It is natu ral and normal for every one in the world to be concerned about

  his own family and cherish his own children. The Son of Heaven may

  care for his subjects, but he cannot possibly do better than they can for

  themselves. This has been the case even before the Three Dynasties.

  What the [ancient] sage [kings] did was to transform self- interest of every

  individual person into a common good for all, with his own person serv-

 

‹ Prev