Positional Option Trading (Wiley Trading)

Home > Other > Positional Option Trading (Wiley Trading) > Page 15
Positional Option Trading (Wiley Trading) Page 15

by Euan Sinclair


  we can also see clearly that when things go wrong, selling teeny

  options is far more painful than selling those with more premium.

  In summary, when selling strangles or condors we want to take

  advantage of the skew premium, but if we do this by selling the

  option with the highest implied volatility, we expose ourselves to

  horrendous risk. Once we have found our short put strike, we

  choose the other call strike to give the delta or vega profile we

  want.

  TABLE 6.21 The Summary Statistics from Selling $1000

  Vega of 260/335 SPY Strangles

  Statistic

  Maximum Implied Volatility

  Strangle

  Average

  $3,980

  Standard

  deviation

  $32,430

  Skewness

  −3.4

  Excess kurtosis

  15.1

  Median

  $20,092

  10th percentile

  −$37,100

  Minimum

  −$306,928

  Percent profitable

  76%

  Choosing a Hedging Strike

  129

  The only reason we choose a short-volatility strategy is that we think implied volatility is too high. Consistent with this, any

  option we buy will be one that we think is overpriced. This is true

  even if there is no implied volatility skew. In the presence of a

  skew we will be overpaying by even more. The long-hedging

  options have negative expected value. They are a cost of doing

  business. We want to choose the ones that give us our desired

  amount of protection for the smallest amount of money.

  As an example, consider the case in which we sell a 260 put for

  6.28 and we don't want a possible loss of more than $5,000. Our

  possible hedging options are shown in Table 6.22. The process is simple. We just find the hedging strike that gives the loss level we

  are comfortable with for the lowest cost.

  Maximum Loss = Profit of Hedge + Loss of Short Put − Hedge

  Premium + Short Put Premium

  So here, we would buy the 205 put for a hedge cost of $145.

  Ignoring option premia, the worst P/L will occur right at the long

  strike. Here we will have lost money on our short and have got

  nothing from the long. Below the strike, the long put and short put

  will cancel completely. Because our loss limit is $5,000 this would

  put the lower put strike at 210. However, total premia received

  will be $628 hedge premium, so the strike will be lowered by this

  amount (divided by 100).

  TABLE 6.22 Prices and Strikes of Possible Hedging Options for Our Short 260 Put Position

  Strik

  Market

  Max Loss of Hedged

  e

  Price

  Portfolio

  180

  0.64

  $7,436

  185

  0.74

  $6,946

  190

  0.88

  $6,460

  195

  1.05

  $5,977

  200

  1.23

  $5,495

  205

  1.45

  $5,017

  210

  1.68

  $4,540

  215

  1.95

  $4,067

  220

  2.25

  $3,597

  130

  It can be tempting to buy lower premia, shorter-dated options as

  hedges. This is almost always a bad idea. Generally, the

  consecutively purchased short-dated options will have a higher

  total premium than the single longer-dated option (a consequence

  of total variance scaling with the square root of time). If we also

  consider the extra transaction costs, the single option becomes

  even more attractive.

  We can illustrate this general rule and also show how exceptions

  to it can occur by using the Brenner and Subrahmanyam (1988)

  approximation. They show that for ATM options the BSM

  equation is approximated by

  (6.2)

  Take this to be our hedging benchmark and compare it to the

  alternative of buying two options consecutively. In that case, the

  hedging premium would be

  (6.3)

  The two-option hedge is more expensive if the volatility term

  structure is flat. However, if the volatility term structure is steep

  enough, it could be worth rolling the shorter term hedges.

  Specifically if the volatilities for each subperiod, σ 1 and σ 2, and the total volatility, σ, are related by

  (6.4)

  then it is worthwhile rolling shorter-dated hedges.

  As an example, consider the situation in which we can either buy a

  2-year option or a 1-year option and then another 1-year option

  when the first one expires. The stock is $100, the strike is 100,

  volatility is 30%, and rates are zero. The 2-year put is worth 16.8.

  Each single 1-year put is worth 11.9. So here the 2-year option is

  the cheaper alternative.

  131

  But consider the case where the 2-year option has an implied

  volatility of 40% and the 1-year option has an implied volatility of

  20%. Also assume that this term structure is constant in time, so

  when the first 1-year option expires we can buy the next one at

  20% as well. Now each 1-year option is worth 8.0 and the 2-year

  option is worth 22.3. Here, we are better off buying a 1-year option

  and rolling it later.

  Expiration Choice

  As I've emphasized throughout this chapter, there is more to

  choosing an option to trade than simply finding the one that has

  the highest expected return. Many other metrics are also relevant.

  Median return, drawdown exposure, and percent of trades that are

  profitable are also statistics to consider. However, it also seems

  reasonable that our search can start with expected value and

  expand from there. The purpose of trading is to make money. Risk

  management should aim to protect expected value rather than

  minimize risk. The safest position is no position. That will also

  make no money.

  The profitability of option trading is driven by the variance

  premium. Many other effects are important but the variance

  premium will always be dominant. It is to options what evolution

  is to biology or what gravity is to physics. So when choosing an

  expiration our prime consideration is which one has the most

  variance premium. If we are selling, we want the expiration with

  the highest premium. If we are buying, we want the expiration

  with the lowest premium.

  Israelov and Tummala (2017) studied this problem and wrote a

  paper whose title is the perfect statement of our issue: “Which

  Index Options Should You Sell?” By looking at S&P 500 option

  performances from 1996 to 2015, they showed that short-dated

  options had the highest variance premia. Their explanation for

  this was this:

  Option buyers seek to purchase insurance for their portfolio

  and are typically concerned about monthly or quarterly

  returns.… It is intuitive that the options which most directly

  match these preferences are the most attractively

  compensated for option sellers. (p. 14)

  132

 
This is quite possibly true, but I think the more important reason is compensation for risk. Short-dated option risk is dominated by

  gamma, and long-dated option risk is due to vega. The old story is

  “vega wounds but gamma kills.” The sellers of short-dated options

  are taking the most risk and they should be most compensated. A

  good rule when looking for a variance premium is to look for

  situations with the most risk. The variance premium is (a

  mispriced) compensation for risk. The higher the risk, the higher

  the mispricing.

  This hypothesis is consistent with the results of Tosi and Ziegler

  (2017). Using S&P 500 option data from 1996 to 2015 they showed

  that the returns from shorting out-of-the-money put options were

  concentrated in the few days preceding their expiration. Back-

  month options generated almost no returns.

  Their proffered reason for this was:

  The concentration of the option premium at the end of the

  cycle reflects changes in options' risk characteristics.

  Specifically, options' convexity risk increases sharply close to

  maturity, making them more sensitive to jumps in the

  underlying price. By contrast, volatility risk plays a smaller

  role close to maturity. (abstract)

  And conclude:

  Our results imply that speculators wishing to harvest the put

  option premium should short front-month options only

  during the last days of the cycle, while investors wishing to

  protect against downside risk should use back-month options

  to reduce hedging costs. (abstract)

  Other studies that reach the same conclusion are by Andries et al.

  (2015), Dew-Becker et al. (2014), and van Binsbergen and Koijen

  (2015).

  Conclusion

  There is no “best” strategy. The choice of what to select is a matter

  of personal risk preferences. Strangles win more often than

  straddles but have less upside and more downside. Butterflies and

  condors are more expensive than straddles and strangles in terms

  of transaction costs. They will also realize their maximum possible

  loss a significant amount of the time.

  133

  When choosing a short strike, the trader needs to balance

  receiving the most edge by selling the options with the highest

  implied volatility and the amount of risk that this produces.

  Similarly, shorter-dated options will have more variance premium

  than longer-dated ones but they also have more potential for

  catastrophe.

  Summary

  Selling OTM option structures (strangles or condors) will give

  higher median returns and a higher win percentage but this

  can make it more difficult to distinguish between good trades

  with expected value and good luck.

  The highest volatility premium is in short-dated options. Long-

  dated options have very little volatility premium.

  The highest volatility premium is in far-out-of-the-money

  puts. Out-of-the-money calls have very little volatility

  premium.

  134

  CHAPTER 7

  Directional Option Trading

  The genius of the BSM model is the idea that the direction of the

  underlying doesn't matter when pricing an option. But although this

  methodology leads to an arbitrage-free replication value, it is still possible

  to trade options to make bets on the underlying direction. If one believes

  the story of Thales and the olive presses, this was the original point of

  options. Even now most traders use options directionally. Indeed, many

  retail traders can only buy options, and directional trading is essentially

  their only available tactic.

  In this chapter, I will discuss directional option speculation, starting with

  the theory of pricing with a directional view and then discussing the choice

  of strikes, structures, and expirations. All examples will be given in terms

  of long calls, assuming a bullish bias, but the ideas are trivially

  generalizable to both puts and short option positions. I'm also going to

  assume each option is on one share.

  Subjective Option Pricing

  Options offer many advantages over trading the underlying. The main

  advantage is the ability to speculate on a more nuanced view than just “up

  or down.” Also, leverage and the possibility of highly skewed payoffs can be

  useful. However, these all add considerable complexity.

  Here I'm going to (possibly optimistically) assume that the trader has a

  valid prediction method for the underlying and show how she should

  monetize this view. It is never easy to predict the direction of the

  underlying. But when trading options, it is easy to be right in your

  prediction of the underlying and still lose money. It is never good to solve

  the hardest part of a problem and still fail.

  The simplest directional option trading strategy is to buy a call if you think

  the underlying will expire above the strike by more than the option

  premium. This can be kindly characterized as “model-free directional

  trading” and more realistically as “guessing.”

  Consider this set of call prices on a $100 stock:

  Strik Pric

  e

  e

  95

  8.7

  100

  5.6

  105

  3.2

  135

  Strik Pric

  e

  e

  110

  1.5

  If we know the stock will expire at $120, our strike choice is trivial.

  Investing $100 in each option would give the following profits:

  Strik Profit

  e

  95

  $187

  100

  $257

  105

  $369

  110

  $567

  But the problems with trading are never about optimizing results when

  predictions are correct. The real issue is how to control risk when we are

  wrong. If the stock only goes to $106, our profits will be completely

  different:

  Strik Profit

  e

  95

  $26

  100

  $7

  105

  −$68

  110

  −$100

  These extreme differences illustrate the need for a better plan.

  A Theory of Subjective Option Pricing

  The dynamic hedging strategy used in the BSM model removes the need to

  use a drift parameter. But that isn't to say that we can't include drift in our personal pricing. We won't be in the risk-neutral paradigm anymore and

  our theoretical values will disagree with market prices, but that is to be

  expected. If we agreed with market prices, we wouldn't be speculating.

  BSM showed that the rate of return of the underlying is not relevant for

  pricing options. But the underlying return obviously does affect the return of the unhedged option.

  If we have a valuation model that explicitly includes drift, we can use it to

  compare the theoretical values to market prices and find the most

  attractive opportunities.

  Luckily, several pre-BSM pricing models did include the return on the

  stock. Boness (1962, 1964) found an option pricing model that is

  functionally the same as BSM but is bas
ed in the real, rather than the risk-

  neutral, world. It isn't arbitrage free, but it answers the most important

  136

  question a directional speculator has: If she thinks the stock is going up,

  what option should she buy?

  Instead of calculating the call value by taking the expectation of the payoff

  in the risk-neutral world, Boness's result is the expectation in the physical

  world.

  With the normal notation:

  (7.1)

  (7.2)

  where

  (7.3)

  (7.4)

  To arrive at this formula, Boness had to make an assumption about

  returns.

  He needed to say that the stock return is the rate used to discount the

  strike in the put-call relationship, that is, all cash flows would be invested

  in the stock.

  In the normal derivation of put-call parity, we form a portfolio that is long

  a put, short a call, and long a share. At expiration this portfolio is worth the strike price, which means the portfolio is currently worth the discounted

  strike value. Since the middle ages (where the idea was used as the basis for

  mortgage lending) it has been known that the correct discount factor is the

  interest rate. Drift is irrelevant. If anything other than the interest rate is

  used as a discount factor, an arbitrage opportunity exists.

  Even if we accept that drift is a real phenomenon, it is also reasonable to

  include an interest rate as an alternative investment opportunity. The stock

  appreciates at μ and cash is stored at r. It might appear that no investor would operate like this. If μ > r, why would he not invest all money in the stock and ignore the interest rate completely (Boness's model does this)?

  In reality, people generally do split investments between assets with

  137

  different returns and risks. The stock has a higher return but also higher

  risk, which is reflected in the volatility parameter.

  It is possible to construct a pricing model that does this with a formal

  argument from a modified BSM PDE. But this isn't necessary. Our model

  needs to assume cash is invested at a risk-free interest rate and the forward

  price of the stock is driven by a (physical world) drift.

  If we slightly reinterpret some parameters, this model already exists: the

  generalized BSM prices (European) options when the underlying pays a

  continuous dividend yield. We use this, and the interest rate, to price

  options of the forward value of the stock while also assuming that cash

 

‹ Prev