The Growth Delusion

Home > Other > The Growth Delusion > Page 2
The Growth Delusion Page 2

by David Pilling


  * * *

  —

  We live in a society in which a priesthood of technically trained economists, wielding impenetrable mathematical formulas, sets the framework for public debate. Ultimately, it is the economists who determine how much we can spend on our schools, public libraries, and armies, how much unemployment is acceptable or whether it is right to print money or bail out profligate banks.

  Bill Clinton’s “It’s the economy, stupid” meant voters only cared about the state of the economy. At the time this carried more than a grain of truth. Though few people could give a precise definition of what the economy actually was, many did vote according to their perception of how it was performing. That might be based on personal experience: whether their job felt secure and their mortgage payments manageable. But two quarters of something as nebulous as negative growth—the technical definition of a recession—could be enough to bury a political career. Voters had been hijacked by an abstract concept.

  Since then something has changed. The backlash we are witnessing suggests that people are calling time on the economists and their faulty representation of our lives. That can be very liberating. It can also be very dangerous. We don’t want non-experts building our bridges, flying our planes, or performing open-heart surgery. Do we want non-economists running our economies? The problem with economists is that they often claim a scientific precision that their profession does not merit. They also speak a language that fails to resonate with people’s lived experience. That is why it is so important for citizens to learn the rudiments of the economists’ lingo, to gain the tools to analyze what they are being told and to demand change if necessary.

  Defenders of GDP say it was never meant to reflect well-being. To criticize it for failing to capture everything important in life is like blaming a tape measure for not telling us about a person’s weight or personality. That would be a valid rejoinder if the economy were just another concept, one of many we used to judge how we are doing as societies. But economic growth has become a fetish, a proxy for everything we are supposed to care about and an altar on which we are prepared to sacrifice all. In pursuit of growth, we are told, we may have to work longer hours, slash public services, accept greater inequality, give up our privacy, and let “wealth-creating” bankers have free rein. If environmentalists are right, the pursuit of growth without end could even threaten the very existence of humanity, ransacking our biodiversity and driving us to unsustainable levels of consumption and CO2 emission that wreck the very planet on which our wealth depends. Only in economics is endless expansion seen as a virtue. In biology it is called cancer.11

  Guiding you gently through the technicalities of GDP is one of the purposes of these chapters. So too is fleshing out the possible alternatives—none of them perfect—from measures of wealth, equality, and sustainability to indicators of “subjective well-being” (happiness to you and me).

  The aim of this book is not to declare war on growth. Some will fault it for that. Rather it is to show what is wrong with our measurement of growth in the hope that we can knock it from its pedestal. The way we measure our economies has its logic, though it is becoming less logical as we shift from manufacturing to services and from analog to digital. But it is a very narrow measure, a slit of a window through which to view our world. We need to broaden our perspective so that the image we capture is more reflective of our lives.

  This book came about because, after twenty years of reporting for the Financial Times from five continents, I have reached the conclusion that our habit of seeing everything through the prism of economic growth is distorting our view of what is important. I know because I learned how to do it. From my very first days reporting from Latin America in the 1990s I taught myself how to compare every number to GDP and to mention it in almost every article—to lend a bit of gravitas. I didn’t spend too much time worrying about what exactly GDP was or what it was supposed to mean.

  Only years later did I begin to give it more thought. One catalyst was my experience in Japan in the mid-2000s, reporting on a country whose economy, in conventional terms, had stalled. Japan was regularly written about as though it were some kind of basket case stuck in perpetual stagnation and without the wits to haul itself out of misery. None of this felt right. Certainly, Japan had problems and it was true that its economic miracle, which had so astonished the world in the 1980s, had run out of steam. But Japan’s supposed misery—as measured by nominal GDP—really didn’t feel like misery at all.12 Unemployment was extremely low, prices stable or falling, and most people’s living standards rising. Communities were intact, certainly in comparison to those in America, Britain, and France. Crime was low, drug use almost nonexistent, the quality of food and consumer goods world class, and health and life expectancy among the highest in the world.13 And yet, viewed through the prism of economics, Japan was an abject failure.

  Economics can present a distorted view of the world. So much of what is important to us, from clean air to safe streets and from steady jobs to sound minds, lies outside its range of vision. Of course, we could just throw up our hands and let others worry about the precise definition of economic growth. But that would mean recusing ourselves from the debate. It would mean leaving everything that matters in life to the self-designated experts. And look where that has got us.

  * For the purposes of this book, unless otherwise stated, “the economy” and “GDP” are interchangeable terms since we define the economy by the size of its GDP. The economy will also sometimes appear as “national income.” GDP growth is synonymous with growth.

  1

  KUZNETS’S MONSTER

  For most of human history the workings of what we casually refer to as “the economy” were pretty much a black box. Indeed, for millennia the concept of an economy hardly existed at all. There were at least two reasons for this. First, before the eighteenth-century Industrial Revolution, there was really no such thing as economic growth. That made the economy an awful lot duller. The output of agricultural societies was pretty much a function of the weather. If rains were good, the harvest was good. If not, it wasn’t. Nor, in this pre-industrial world, were there huge productivity gaps between one region and another. Most people were just scraping by. Thus the size of a region’s economy was largely determined by the size of its population. In AD 1000 China and India accounted for just over half of global economic output, a proportion that remained unchanged for 600 years (and may be heading that way again).1

  Second, in an era of monarchs—especially those lucky enough to have been ordained by God—what was going on in the broader economy was of no great concern. For an absolute monarch there was no distinction between his own wealth and that of his realm.2 Given the lack of distinction between the wealth of the monarch and the wealth of the nation, there was little room for anything we might call an economy. Apart from keeping the court in its accustomed luxury, the only thing required of a national economy was to finance war. A nation grew only if it conquered new dominions. If the king could muster armies to grab new territory, the national weal would be increased. But how could you tell whether your nation could bear the cost? Most early attempts to catalog the size of an economy were driven by the need to work out the monarch’s capacity to wage war.3

  So it was in France. In 1781 Jacques Necker, the Swiss finance minister of Louis XVI, presented his famous compte rendu au roi, his “report to the king,” the first attempt to take serious stock of France’s finances. Necker, formerly a wildly successful banker—are the alarm bells going off yet?—showed that France’s finances were in rude health. Revenues were said to exceed expenditure by the enormous sum of 10 million livres. The main purpose of the report was to demonstrate that France could easily afford its involvement in the American Revolutionary War, in which, as was customary, it found itself on the opposite side to Britain. Necker, who had made his own fortune through speculation, wanted to prove that France
’s finances were so solid it could easily borrow money to finance its war effort. What the compte rendu cleverly omitted, however, was that France had already borrowed heavily under Necker’s own direction. One of the earliest attempts to present a set of national accounts was also a piece of fiction.

  Necker’s stab at national accounting was not the first. That distinction is usually given to William Petty, whose publication of the Down Survey in 1652 is considered by many to be the first systematic effort to survey a country’s economy—in this case, that of Ireland.4 With the help of simple instruments and a thousand unemployed soldiers, Petty undertook the comprehensive mapping of land in thirty counties covering 5 million acres. The principal motivation was to carve up Catholic land conquered by Oliver Cromwell and to use it to pay back those who had financed the war as well as the arrears of soldiers’ wages. In addition to mapping the land, Petty conducted a fairly rigorous survey of assets, including ships, houses, and personal estates. From this he worked out flows of income that would be generated, a crucial distinction from earlier efforts to catalog stocks of wealth such as the Domesday Book of 1086.

  Later, after the restoration of King Charles II, Petty did the same in England and Wales. This time the objective was to improve the monarch’s capacity to tax his subjects. Petty recommended keeping records on domestic consumption, production, trade, and population growth and started to develop methods for assessing the value of labor as well as land.

  If early attempts to survey the economy had common themes of war, taxation, and subservience to the monarch’s needs, there were other schools of thought pulling in a different direction. In France in the eighteenth century the so-called physiocrats emphasized that the wealth of a nation was rooted in farm production and productive work. Subtly different from Petty, in the physiocrats’ interpretation the “productive class” consisted of mainly agricultural laborers, while the so-called sterile class included “artisans, professionals, merchants and, lo and behold, the King himself.”5 Viewed from this perspective, the invention of the economy—as something distinct from the monarch—was a profoundly democratic act.

  Adam Smith, in his An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, first published in 1776, also divided labor into productive and unproductive categories. A man, he wrote, “grows rich by employing a multitude of manufacturers: He grows poor by maintaining a multitude of menial servants.” It wasn’t a very flattering view of the leisured classes. Along with hosts of servants performing useless tasks for do-nothing aristocrats, the monarch, as well as the army and the navy, were put into the category of unproductive labor.

  What unites these early attempts to catalog national wealth is an effort to draw what economists today call the production boundary—between activities that should be counted and those that should not. In short, they were trying to answer a question that is still relevant today: precisely what is an economy? In the great economic ledger should the king appear on the plus side, the embodiment in flesh and blood of the national patrimony? Or, as the physiocrats and Adam Smith implied, should he be on the negative side of the ledger, an unproductive spender of the nation’s resources?

  The same question of what should be included and what should be excluded has rumbled on ever since. Should we include government spending? How about providers of services, whose contributions to society—healthy minds (psychoanalysts), humor (clowns), education (teachers)—may be harder to count than horseshoes or bushels of wheat? In the twentieth century communist countries largely ignored services altogether. Even today we struggle to measure their economic contribution.

  Modern national accounts of the type used by virtually every country in the world today only really began to take shape in the 1930s. Simon Kuznets is usually credited with the invention of GDP, the quintessence of the national accounting system. But Kuznets, rather like Victor Frankenstein, soon saw his creation take on a life—and a direction—of its own.

  * * *

  —

  The man who is said to have invented our way of measuring growth was born in 1901 into a merchant family in the town of Pinsk in what was then part of the Russian empire. Pinsk had a large Jewish population and Kuznets’s parents were Belarusian Jews. As a child he lived under the rule of the tsar, and as an adolescent sympathized with the Mensheviks, whose hopes of reforming tsarist Russia were swept aside by the Bolshevik revolution of October 1917.6 Kuznets then studied at Kharkiv University in Ukraine, where he attended the Institute of Commerce and studied economics, history, statistics, and mathematics. He was a young man of great social conscience and ideals.

  His tutors at Kharkiv stressed the importance of basing opinions on empirical data, a lesson that stayed with him for life. There was also an emphasis on placing economic theory in a wider historical and social context. Kuznets was a brilliant student and by his early twenties had published his first paper on the wages of factory workers in Kharkiv. His studies at the university were interrupted by the Russian civil war, and in 1922 the family fled, via Turkey, to the US. It was here that the Belarusian émigré was to make a profound and lasting impact on global economics.

  Kuznets continued his education at Columbia University, graduating in 1923 and receiving his PhD in 1926. The following year he joined the National Bureau of Economic Research, a think tank founded in 1920. Kuznets would become a distinguished academic economist with something any self-respecting economist aspires to—a curve named after him.7 (Oh, and he also won a Nobel Prize in economics in 1971.) His most lasting achievement, however, came in the intersection between economics and the real world.

  Kuznets loved data. He worked closely with the first director of research at the National Bureau of Economic Research, Wesley Mitchell, who was also chairman of President Herbert Hoover’s Committee on Social Trends. That work took Kuznets into the heart of government policy. Hoover’s election campaign had promised Americans “a chicken in every pot and a car in every garage.” What they got instead was the Wall Street Crash and the Great Depression. Hoover’s response to the terrible depression that followed, which at its trough saw at least one in every four Americans without work, was slow and inadequate. Essentially, he thought the economy would heal itself. Prosperity, he assured Americans, was just around the corner.

  Hoover may not have been entirely to blame. There was no systematic methodology for drawing up an accurate picture of a national economy. A publication in 2000 by the US Department of Commerce, which praised GDP as “one of the great inventions of the 20th century,” quotes an economist as saying, “One reads with dismay of Presidents Hoover and then Roosevelt designing policies to combat the Great Depression of the 1930s on the basis of such sketchy data as stock price indices, freight-car loadings and incomplete indices of industrial production.” As hard as it is to believe now in this age of obsession with economic statistics, Hoover had only the crudest notion of what was actually going on.

  That was about to change. When Franklin D. Roosevelt became president in 1933, Kuznets was entrusted with the task of creating national accounts. Kuznets outlined his ideas in an article for the Encyclopedia of Social Sciences. His notion was disarmingly simple: to squeeze all human activity into a single number.

  Kuznets was the ideal man for the job. He had a near-obsession with measuring things. One writer compares his way of analyzing an economy to a doctor on his patient rounds. He based his assessment on observable data and symptoms. But understanding the patient’s underlying condition also required judgment, knowledge, and a rigorous inquisition of the facts. For Kuznets, being thorough was more important than being brilliant.8

  Kuznets began by categorizing American industry into different sectors, such as energy, manufacturing, mining, and agriculture. He was given a staff of three assistants and five statistical clerks. “Together they hit the road, visiting factories, mines and farms, interviewing owners and managers and writing down figures in n
otebooks.”9 Although the scale of data collection is vastly bigger these days, survey-based methodology hasn’t changed that much even in the era of big data. To this day sizing up an economy remains primarily an extrapolation of survey data, not a summation of gathered facts.

  Kuznets’s team traveled the length and breadth of the USA asking farmers and factory managers what and how much they had produced and what they had purchased in order to make their final product. The team shared data so they could compare results and iron out anomalies. Kuznets knew the data were more or less meaningless in isolation. They had to be interpreted. Though it would take many more years before the first publication, in 1942, of a full set of gross national product statistics, Kuznets’s work bore much earlier fruit.10 In January 1934 he presented his first report to Congress. It ran to 261 pages and, for such a historic document, bore a name that only an economist could dream up: National Income, 1929–32.

  The report began with much throat clearing about what the numbers could and could not reveal. His effort was, Kuznets said, “an amalgam of…estimates,” at best “only well-considered guesses.”11 The welfare of a nation, he made clear, could “scarcely be inferred” from such an estimate. Contained within its pages, however, was a bombshell. In the three years following the Wall Street Crash the American economy had almost halved in size.

  Kuznets’s findings became the basis for the second, much more ambitious, phase of Roosevelt’s New Deal, in which the government spent massively on public works, farm aid, and social security in order to pull the US economy out of its seemingly interminable recession. Kuznets had provided a more rigorous empirical foundation on which to take such radical action than freight-car loadings. Still, he had warned that the estimates of national income were “of little value in themselves.” The headline number was not what was important, he said in words that should ring louder than ever today. For example, closer analysis showed that inequality had increased greatly during the Great Depression. Blue-collar wages had fallen much faster than white-collar salaries, and property owners had fared better than most. These findings provided Roosevelt with the evidence he needed to push through his radical employment policies, which included unemployment relief, the banning of child labor, and the right of labor unions to organize. Without Kuznets’s report, much of this would have been impossible.

 

‹ Prev