Popularity as a Bridge between Classical and Behavioral Finance
The title of this book refers to popularity as a bridge between classical and behavioral finance. Both approaches to finance rest on investor preferences, which we recast as popularity.
Classical finance is based on the following principles: rationality, equilibrium or risk-free arbitrage, and efficient markets with “fair” pricing. In this book, we took the equilibrium approach.
In classical finance, risk—in particular, systematic risk—is the primary aversion of investors. A single systematic risk is priced in the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), but some risks, including various types of stock or bond risks, can also be multidimensional. The specific structure of risk can also be priced, as in catastrophic risk.
Although classical finance usually assumes away market frictions, rational investors may have preferences for market liquidity, favorable tax treatments, or asset divisibility, making assets more or less valuable to the extent they embody these characteristics.
In behavioral finance, investors may not be completely rational. Thus, investors may have preferences that go beyond rational behavior.
We classified behavioral biases into two types, psychological and cognitive. Psychological desires cause some assets to be more popular than others, relative to their risk-adjusted expected cash flows and relative to such other rational characteristics as liquidity. Investors’ rationality is also limited because they make cognitive errors.
Neoclassical economics provides the rationality framework for efficient capital markets, CAPM, New Equilibrium Theory (NET), and so on. Behavioral economics assumes limited or “bounded” rationality and thus provides the framework for prospect theory, loss aversion, framing, mental accounting, overconfidence, and similar cognitive biases.
Popularity represents preferences, which can be rational or irrational. Thus, popularity provides a bridge between classical and behavioral finance.
Popularity as a Theory
The CAPM is an elegant and easy-to-use theory for describing investor expected returns in an equilibrium setting. We generalized the CAPM to include all types of preferences in the popularity asset pricing model (PAPM).
The CAPM assumes that investors are not only rational and risk averse but can also diversify away all unsystematic risk. Thus, only systematic (market) risk in securities is priced. Securities with high systematic risk have lower relative prices and, therefore, higher expected returns.
NET is a framework in which investors are rational but have preferences for or aversions to various security characteristics beyond undiversifiable market risk, as in the CAPM—even beyond the multiple dimensions of risk modeled in the arbitrage pricing theory.
In NET, in addition to systematic risk aversion, investors also have a rational aversion to assets that are difficult to diversify, lack liquidity, are highly taxed, and/or are not easily divisible. All these preferences affect the prices and expected returns of assets that embody these characteristics.
The PAPM provides a theory in a CAPM equilibrium framework by including both risk aversion and popularity preferences on the part of investors. These preferences can be rational, as in NET, or irrational, as in behavioral economics.
In the PAPM, the various securities have different systematic and unsystematic risks and differing popularity characteristics. Investors also have differing risk aversions and popularity preferences. The characteristics are priced according to the aggregate demand for each of the characteristics. The expected return of each security is determined by its risk and popularity characteristics.
In our PAPM illustration, one investor, having only risk aversion and no popularity preferences, was purely rational. Although this investor earned excess economic returns, he or she was only part of the equilibrium demand, so aggregate popularity was still a part of PAPM pricing. Securities are priced in this equilibrium framework, and no riskless arbitrage opportunities exist.
Empirical Evidence for Popularity
The concept of a negative return to popularity (what we have simply called “popularity”) has been shown to be consistent with the empirical premiums found in the stock market. But this explanation is after the fact. Direct tests involve trying to identify in advance what characteristics are likely to be popular and which ones are likely to be unpopular and then to test the relative performance of portfolios based on them. We did this test at the company level and at the common stock level.
We carried out analyses on five characteristics: (1) brand, (2) competitive advantage, (3) reputation, (4) tail risk, and (5) lottery-like stocks. In the analyses, we considered both equally weighted composites and market cap–weighted composites. Of these 10 different views, all 10 are highly consistent to moderately consistent with popularity whereas only 5 of 10 are consistent with the paradigm that more risk equals more return.
Companies with high brand values are popular. The quartile portfolios containing these companies ended up having significantly lower returns than the quartile portfolios with the lowest brand value over the April 2000–August 2017 period.
Companies with sustainable competitive advantages are said to have wide economic moats, making them more popular than low-moat or no-moat companies. Portfolios of companies with no moats outperformed portfolios of wide-moat companies over the July 2002–August 2017 period.
Quartile portfolios of companies with better reputations tended to underperform quartile portfolios of companies with less glowing reputations over the April 2000–August 2017 period.
Equities that have historically had negative tail-risk events (low or negative coskewness) are unpopular. Quartile portfolios of these stocks significantly outperformed those of stocks with high coskewness over the January 1996–August 2017 period.
Stocks with lottery-like payoffs are popular because they provide the apparent opportunity for outsized gains. Quartile portfolios of these stocks, specifically those with the highest average of their five best days’ returns, had the lowest risk-adjusted returns among the quartile portfolios based on this measure of lottery-like payoffs over the February 1991– December 2016 period.
We also examined the well-known premiums and anomalies for the 1972–2016 period by analyzing 10 applicable sets of factor-based quartile portfolios in Ibbotson and Kim (2017) through the popularity lens. Ibbotson and Kim found that quartile portfolios of low-beta, low-volatility, small-capitalization, value, less liquidity, and high-momentum stocks outperformed their opposites. Of the 10 factors that we analyzed, 7 are consistent with the popularity framework, whereas only 2 out of 10 are consistent with the classical risk–return view. Overall, we found that for most categories in the stock market, an inverse relationship exists between risk and return, counter to classical theory. Either risk is popular in some circumstances or other, nonrisk characteristics dominate returns. We believe that popularity reflects the demand that ultimately determines prices and returns.
Popularity is a framework that can be used to model asset values and expected returns. Most existing financial literature, whether classical or behavioral, is consistent with popularity. Our new research is also consistent with popularity. Thus, popularity is a bridge between classical and behavioral finance.
References
Amihud, Yakov. 2002. “Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Cross-Section and Time-Series Effects.” Journal of Financial Markets 5 (1): 31–56.
Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson. 1986. “Asset Pricing and the Bid-Ask Spread.” Journal of Financial Economics 17 (2): 223–49.
Ang, Andrew. 2014. Asset Management: A Systematic Approach to Factor Investing . New York: Oxford University Press.
Ang, Andrew, Robert J. Hodrick, Yuhang Xing, and Xiaoyan Zhang. 2006. “The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns.” Journal of Finance 61 (1): 259–99.
Anginer, Deniz, and Meir Statman. 2010. “Stocks of Admired and Spurned Companies.” Journal of Portfolio Management 36 (3): 71–77.
Ar
nott, Robert D., Jason Hsu, and Philip Moore. 2005. “Fundamental Indexation.” Financial Analysts Journal 61 (2): 83–99.
Asness, Clifford S., Andrea Frazzini, and Lasse H. Pedersen. 2012. “Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity.” Financial Analysts Journal 68 (1): 47–59.
Atukeren, Erdal, and Aylin Seçkin. 2007. “On the Valuation of Psychic Returns to Art Market Investments.” Economic Bulletin 26 (5): 1–12.
Baker, Malcolm, Brendan Bradley, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2011. “Benchmarks as Limits to Arbitrage: Understanding the Low-Volatility Anomaly.” Financial Analysts Journal 67 (1): 40–54.
Baker, Nardin L., and Robert A. Haugen. 2012. “Low Risk Stocks Outperform within All Observable Markets in the World.” Available at SSRN.
Bali, Turan, Nusret Cakici, and Robert Whitelaw. 2011. “Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 99 (2): 427–46.
Bansal, Ravi, and Amir Yaron. 2004. “Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles.” Journal of Finance 59 (4): 1481–509.
Banz, Rolf W. 1981. “The Relationship between Return and Market Value of a Common Stock.” Journal of Financial Economics 9 (1): 3–18.
Barber, Brad M., and Terrance Odean. 2008. “All That Glitters: The Effect of Attention and News on the Buying Behavior of Individual and Institutional Investors.” Review of Financial Studies 21 (2): 785–818.
Barberis, Nicholas, and Ming Huang. 2008. “Stocks as Lotteries: The Implications of Probability Weighting for Security Prices.” American Economic Review 98 (5): 2066–100.
Barth, Mary E., Michael Clement, George Foster, and Ron Kasznik. 1998. “Brand Values and Capital Market Valuation.” Review of Accounting Studies 3 (1–2): 41–68.
Basu, Sanjoy. 1977. “Investment Performance of Common Stocks in Relation to Their Price-Earnings Ratios: A Test of the Efficient Market Hypothesis.” Journal of Finance 32 (3): 663–82.
———. 1983. “The Relationship between Earnings Yield, Market Value, and Return for NYSE Common Stocks: Further Evidence.” Journal of Financial Economics 12 (1): 129–56.
Baumol, W.J. 1986. “Unnatural Value: Or Art Investment as Floating Crap Game.” American Economic Review 76 (2): 10–14.
Benartzi, Shlomo, and Richard Thaler. 1995. “Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1): 73–92.
Berk, Jonathan B. 1997. “Does Size Really Matter?” Financial Analysts Journal 53 (5): 12–18.
Black, Fischer. 1972. “Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing.” Journal of Business 45 (3): 444–55.
Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes. 1973. “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities.” Journal of Political Economy 81 (3): 637–54.
Blitz, David, and Pim van Vliet. 2007. “The Volatility Effect: Lower Risk without Lower Return.” Journal of Portfolio Management 34 (1): 102–13.
Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane. 1999. “By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Supply Market Behavior.” Journal of Political Economy 107 (2): 205–51.
Candela, Guido, Massimiliano Castellani, and Pierpaolo Pattitoni. 2013. “Reconsidering Psychic Return in Art Investments.” Economics Letters 118 (2): 351–54.
Carhart, Mark M. 1997. “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance.” Journal of Finance 52 (1): 57–82.
Chanel, Olivier L., Louis-André Gérard-Varet, and Victor Ginsburgh. 1994. “Prices and Returns on Paintings: An Exercise on How to Price the Priceless.” GENEVA PAPERS on Risk and Insurance Theory 19 (1): 7–21.
Clarke, Roger, Harindra de Silva, and Steven Thorley. 2011. “Minimum Variance Portfolio Composition.” Journal of Portfolio Management 37 (2): 31–45.
Cochrane, J.H. 2011. “Presidential Address: “Discount Rates.” Journal of Finance 66 (4): 1047–108.
Constantinides, George. 1983. “Capital Market Equilibrium with Personal Tax.” Econometrica 51 (3): 611–36.
Cooper, Lisette, Jeremy Evnine, Jeff Finkelman, Kate Huntington, and David Lynch. 2016. “Social Finance and the Postmodern Portfolio: Theory and Practice.” Journal of Wealth Management 18 (4): 9–21.
Damodaran, Aswath. n.d. “Not Riskless, Not Even Close: Pseudo or Speculative Arbitrage.” Slides, Stern School of Business, New York University. http://people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/invphilslides/session29.pdf .
Datar, Vinay, Narayan Naik, and Robert Radcliffe. 1998. “Liquidity and Stock Returns: An Alternative Test.” Journal of Financial Markets 1 (2): 203–19.
Diermeier, Jeffrey J., Roger G. Ibbotson, and Laurence B. Siegel. 1984. “The Supply of Capital Market Returns.” Financial Analysts Journal 40 (2): 74–80.
Dimson, Elroy, Paul Marsh, and Mike Staunton. 2002. Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns . Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Duca, John V. 2001. “The Democratization of America’s Capital Markets.” Economic and Financial Review , Dallas Fed (Second Quarter): 10–19.
Fama, Eugene F. 1970. “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work.” Journal of Finance 25 (2): 383–417.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1992. “The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance 47 (2): 427–65.
———. 1993. “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics 33 (1): 3–56.
———. 1996. “Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies.” Journal of Finance 51 (1): 55–84.
Fama, Eugene F., and Richard H. Thaler. 2016. “Are Markets Efficient?” Chicago Booth Review (30 June). http://review.chicagobooth.edu/economics/2016/video/are-markets-efficient .
Fehle, Frank, Susan M. Fournier, Thomas J. Madden, and David G. Shrider. 2008. “Brand Value and Asset Pricing.” Quarterly Journal of Finance and Accounting 47 (1): 3–26.
Fisher, Irving. 1930. The Theory of Interest . New York: Macmillan.
Frazzini, Andrea, and Lasse H. Pedersen. 2014. “Betting against Beta.” Journal of Financial Economics 111 (1): 1–25.
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Goetzmann, William N., and Roger G. Ibbotson. 2008. “History and the Equity Risk Premium.” In Handbook of the Equity Risk Premium , edited by R. Mehra, 515–34. North Holland: Elsevier.
Goetzmann, William N., and Alok Kumar. 2008. “Equity Portfolio Diversification.” Review of Finance 12 (3): 433–63.
Graham, Benjamin. 2006. The Intelligent Investor . Revised Edition (originally published in 1949). New York: Harper Collins.
Graham, Benjamin, and David Dodd. 1934. Security Analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Green, Jeremiah, John R.M. Hand, and X. Frank Zhang. 2017. “The Characteristics That Provide Independent Information about Average U.S. Monthly Stock Returns.” Review of Financial Studies 30 (12): 4389–436.
Harris Poll. 2015. “The Harris Poll RQ 2015 Summary Report” (February); downloaded 4 June 2015. http://www.harrisinteractive.com/vault/2015%20RQ%20Media%20Release%20Report_020415.pdf .
Harvey, Campbell R., and Akhtar Siddique. 2000. “Conditional Skewness in Asset Pricing Tests.” Journal of Finance 55 (3): 1263–95.
Harvey, C.R., Y. Liu, and H. Zhu. 2016. “…And the Cross-Section of Expected Returns.” Review of Financial Studies 29 (1): 5–68.
Haugen, Robert A., and Nardin L. Baker. 1991. “The Efficient Market Inefficiency of Capitalization-Weighted Stock Portfolios.” Journal of Portfolio Management 17 (3): 35–40.
———. 1996. Commonality in the Determinants of Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 41 (3): 401–39.
Haugen, Robert A., and A.J. Heins. 1975. “Risk and the Rate of Return on Financial Assets: Some Old Wine in New Bottles.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 10 (5): 775–84.
Hodgson, D.J., and Keith P. Vorkink. 2004. “Asset Pricing Theory and the Valuation of Canadian Paintings.” C
anadian Journal of Economics. Revue Canadienne d’Economique 37 (3): 629–55.
Hong, Harrison, and Marcin Kacperczyk. 2009. “The Price of Sin: The Effects of Social Norms on Markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 93 (1): 15–36.
Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein. 2007. “Disagreement and the Stock Market.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (2): 109–28.
Huang, Jiangwen. 2015. “A Review of Brand Valuation Method.” Journal of Service Science and Management 8 (1): 71–76.
Huss, John, and Thomas Maloney. 2017. “Portfolio Rebalancing: Common Misconceptions.” AQR working paper (February).
Ibbotson, Roger G. 2018. SBBI Yearbook: Stocks, Bonds, Bills, and Inflation, Duff & Phelps . Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley.
Ibbotson, Roger G., Zhiwu Chen, Daniel Y.-J. Kim, and Wendy Y. Hu. 2013. “Liquidity as an Investment Style.” Financial Analysts Journal 69 (3): 30–44.
Ibbotson, Roger G., Jeffrey J. Diermeier, and Laurence B. Siegel. 1984. “The Demand for Capital Market Returns: A New Equilibrium Theory.” Financial Analysts Journal 40 (1): 22–33.
Ibbotson, Roger G., and Peng Chen. 2003. “Long-Run Stock Returns: Participating in the Real Economy.” Financial Analysts Journal 59 (1): 88–98.
Ibbotson, Roger G., and Thomas M. Idzorek. 2014. “Dimensions of Popularity.” Journal of Portfolio Management 40 (5), Special 40th Anniversary Issue: 68–74.
Ibbotson, Roger G., and Daniel Y.-J. Kim. 2017. “Risk and Return within the Stock Market: What Works Best?” Working paper, Zebra Capital Management (30 January).
Ibbotson, Roger G., and Rex Sinquefield. 1976a. “Stocks, Bonds, Bills, and Inflation: Year-by-Year Historical Returns (1926–1974).” Journal of Business 49 (1): 11–47.
Popularity Page 16