Book Read Free

The Mystery of Capital

Page 7

by Hernando De Soto


  The Mystery of Political Awareness

  Hark, hark! the dogs do bark,

  The beggars are coming to town;

  Some in rags and some in jags,

  And some in silken gown.

  —English Nursery Rhyme

  THE BREAKDOWN of population patterns and mandatory law has been an unmistakable trend in developing countries for the past forty years and in former communist countries for the past ten. Since Deng Xiaoping’s economic reforms began in 1979, 100 million Chinese have left their official homes in search of extralegal jobs. Three million illegal migrants besieging Beijing have created a jumble of sweatshops on the outskirts of the city. Port-au-Prince has grown fifteen times larger; Guayaquil eleven times larger, and Cairo four times larger. The underground market now accounts for 50 percent of GDP in Russia and Ukraine and a whopping 62 percent in Georgia. The International Labor Organization reports that since 1990, 85 percent of all new jobs in Latin America and the Caribbean have been created in the extralegal sector. In Zambia, only 10 percent of the workforce is legally employed.

  What are these countries doing about this? Quite a lot. They have rolled up their sleeves and gone to work, addressing each of these problems individually. In August 1999, for example, Bangladeshi authorities demolished 50,000 shanties in the capital city of Dhaka. Where demolition is impossible, governments have built schools and sidewalks for the millions of squatters invading public and private lands. At the same time, governments have supported microfinance programs to assist the sweatshops that are transforming residential areas into industrial zones throughout the world. They have improved the stalls of sidewalk vendors clogging their streets, removed hordes of drifters from their city squares and planted flowers instead, and tightened construction and safety codes to prevent buildings collapsing as they did in Turkey during the 1999 earthquake. Governments have tried to force the independent jitneys and shabby taxis that glut traffic to meet minimum safety standards; they are cracking down on theft and loss of water and electricity and trying to enforce patents and copyrights. They have arrested and executed as many gangsters and drug traffickers as possible (at least the more famous ones) and jailed them (at least for a while); they have tightened security measures to control the influence of extreme political sects among the uprooted and vulnerable multitudes.

  Each of these problems has its own academic specialty to study it and its own political program to cope with it. Few seem to realize that what we have here is one huge, worldwide industrial revolution: a gigantic movement away from life organized on a small scale to life organized on a large one. For better or for worse, people outside the West are fleeing self-sufficient and isolated societies in an effort to raise their standards of living by becoming interdependent in much larger markets.

  What is understood all too rarely is that the Third World and former communist societies are experiencing nearly the same industrial revolution that arrived in the West more than two centuries ago. The difference is that this new revolution is roaring ahead much faster and transforming the lives of many more people. Britain supported just 8 million people when it began its 250-year progression from the farm to the laptop computer. Indonesia is making that same journey in only four decades and carrying a population of more than 200 million. No wonder its institutions have been slow to adapt. But adapt they must. A tide of humanity has moved from isolated communities and households to participate in ever-widening circles of economic and intellectual exchange. It is this tide that has transformed Jakarta, Mexico City, São Paolo, Nairobi, Bombay, Shanghai, and Manila into megacities of 10, 20, 30 million and overwhelmed their political and legal institutions.

  The failure of the legal order to keep pace with this astonishing economic and social upheaval has forced the new migrants to invent extralegal substitutes for established law. Whereas all manner of anonymous business transactions are widespread in advanced countries, the migrants in the developing world can deal only with people they know and trust. Such informal, ad hoc business arrangements do not work very well. The wider the market, as Adam Smith pointed out, the more minute the division of labor can be. And as labor grows more specialized, the economy grows more efficient, and wages and capital values rise. A legal failure that prevents enterprising people from negotiating with strangers defeats the division of labor and fastens would-be entrepreneurs to smaller circles of specialization and low productivity.

  Entrepreneurship triumphed in the West because the law integrated everyone under one system of property, giving them the means to cooperate and produce large amounts of surplus value in an expanded market. The advances of the West, right up to today’s exponential growth of electronic information and telecommunications technology, could happen only because the property rights systems required to make them work were already in place. Integrated legal property systems destroyed most closed groups while inviting the creation of a larger network where the potential to create capital increased substantially. In this sense, property obeys what is known as Metcalfe’s Law (named after Bob Metcalfe, the inventor of the Ethernet Standard that commonly networks personal computers). According to Metcalfe’s Law,

  The value of a network—defined as its utility to a population—is roughly proportional to the number of users squared. An example is the telephone network. One telephone is useless: whom do you call? Two telephones are better, but not much. It is only when most of the population has a telephone that the power of the network reaches its full potential to change society.1

  Like computer networks, which had existed for years before anyone thought to link them, property systems become tremendously powerful when they are interconnected in a larger network. Only then is the potential of a particular property right not limited to the imagination of its owner, his neighbors, or his acquaintances, but subject to a larger network of other imaginations. Only then will people subject themselves to obeying one legal code because they will realize that without that code they will cease to prosper. Only then can government begin to administer development instead of heroically rushing to plug each and every leak. A modern government and a market economy are unviable without an integrated formal property system. Many of the problems of non-Western markets today are due mainly to the fragmentation of their property arrangements and the unavailability of standard norms that allow assets and economic agents to interact and governments to rule by law.

  When migrants move from developing and former communist countries to advanced nations, well-developed institutions eventually absorb them into a networked property system that helps them produce surplus value. The people who migrate within their own countries are not being accommodated in this way—at least not quickly enough. Poorer countries lack the institutions to integrate the migrants into the formal sector, fix their assets into fungible forms, make their owners accountable agents, and provide them with connecting and leveraging devices that allow them to interface productively and generate capital within a large legal market. So the migrants invent, at the expense of the legal order, a variety of extralegal arrangements to substitute for the laws and institutions they need to cooperate in an expanded market.

  Political blindness, therefore, consists of being unaware that the growth of the extralegal sector and the breakdown of the existing legal order are ultimately due to a gigantic movement away from life organized on a small scale toward one organized in a larger context. What national leaders are missing is that people are spontaneously organizing themselves into separate, extralegal groups until government can provide them with one legal property system.

  The fundamental problem for non-Western nations is not that people are moving to urban centers, that garbage is piling up, that infrastructure is insufficient, or that the countryside is being abandoned. All of that happened in advanced nations. Nor is the problem simply urban growth. Los Angeles has grown faster than Calcutta in this century, and Tokyo is three times bigger than Delhi. The primary problem is the delay in recognizing that most of the
disorder occurring outside the West is the result of a revolutionary movement that is more full of promise than of problems. Once the potential value of the movement is harnessed, many of its problems will be easier to resolve. Developing and former communist nations must choose to either create systems that allow their governments to adapt to the continual changes in the revolutionary division of labor or continue to live in extralegal confusion—and that really isn’t much of a choice.

  Why has everyone missed the real problem? Because there are two blind spots. First, most of us do not see that the surge in the world’s extralegal populations over the past forty years has generated a new class of entrepreneurs with their own legal arrangements. Government authorities see only a massive influx of people and illegal workers and the threat of disease and crime. So while the housing ministry deals with its own issues and the ministries of health and justice focus on theirs, no one notices that the real cause of the disorder is not population, or urban growth, or even a poor minority, but an outmoded system of legal property.

  Most of us are like the six blind men in the presence of an elephant: One grasps the animal’s searching trunk and thinks the elephant is a snake; another finds its tail and thinks the elephant is a rope; a third is fascinated by the large, sail-like ears; another embraces its leg and concludes that the elephant is a tree. No one views the elephant in its totality, and thus they cannot come up with a strategy for dealing with the very large problem at hand. As we have seen, the poor in developing and former communist countries constitute two-thirds of the world’s population—and they have no alternative but to live outside the law. As we also saw, the poor have plenty of things, but their property rights are not defined by any law. The millions of enterprising people who fill 85 percent of all new jobs in Latin America, those 3 million Chinese outside Beijing operating illegal sweatshops, and those Russians who generate half of their nation’s GDP are doing so on the basis of extralegal arrangements. More often than not, these grassroots property arrangements openly contradict the official, written law. That is the elephant before us.

  I do not believe the appearance of small enclaves of prosperous economic sectors in the midst of large undeveloped or informal sectors marks the dawn of an uneven but nevertheless inevitable transition to capitalist systems. Rather, the existence of prosperous enclaves in a sea of poverty conceals an abysmal retardation in a nation’s capacity to create, respect, and make available formal property rights to the majority of its citizens.

  The second blind spot is that few recognize that the problems they face are not new. The migration and extralegality plaguing cities in the developing and former communist world closely resemble what the advanced nations of the West went through during their own industrial revolution. They too focused on trying to solve their problems one by one. The lesson of the West is that piecemeal solutions and stopgap measures to alleviate poverty were not enough. Living standards rose only when governments reformed the law and the property system to facilitate the division of labor. With the ability to increase their productivity through the beneficial effects of integrated property systems, ordinary people were able to specialize in ever-widening markets and to increase capital formation.

  Blind Spot I: Life Outside the Bell Jar Today

  Why didn’t we see this new industrial revolution coming? Back in the 1980s, when my colleagues and I in Peru began our work, most officials assumed that our part of the world was to a great extent controlled by law. Latin America had a long, refined, and well-respected legal tradition. To be sure, there were poor people holding jobs and property outside the law, but this extralegal sector was considered relatively small and thus a “marginal” issue. Advanced nations had their share of poverty, unemployment, and black markets, and we had ours. Dealing with them was a job mainly for the police or the handful of academic sociologists who had devoted their careers to studying homegrown exotica. At best, the poor made good copy for National Geographic and the Discovery Channel.

  But no one had any exact data. No one even knew how to measure what the poor were actually doing or precisely how much they owned. And so my colleagues and I decided to put away our books and academic journals, not to mention our reams of government statistics and maps, and visit the real experts on this problem: the poor themselves. Once we went into the streets to look around and listen, we began stumbling across surprising facts. For instance: The Peruvian construction industry was in a slump. Building was down, workers were being laid off. Curiously, however, at outlets for construction materials the cash registers were still ringing. In fact, sales of cement were up. Bags of cement, that is. After further investigation, we discovered that the poor were buying more cement than ever for their construction projects—houses, buildings, and businesses that were not legally registered or titled and therefore never made it onto the computer screens of the government economists and statisticians. We began to sense a vibrant, independent, officially invisible extralegal economy buzzing in the cities throughout the developing world. In Brazil, for example, the construction industry reported a mere 0.1 percent growth in 1995; yet cement sales during the first six months of 1996 soared by nearly 20 percent. The reason for the apparent anomaly, according to a Deutsche Morgan Grenfell analysis is that 60 to 70 percent of the region’s construction never makes it into the records.2

  The extralegal sector, we realized was hardly a small issue. It was enormous.

  Growing Cities

  The movement toward the cities ballooned in the 1960s for most developing countries, and in the 1980s for China. For various reasons, self-reliant communities abandoned their isolation and began trying to integrate in and around cities. Since the 1980s, millions of Chinese peasants have been illegally clustering around cities to the point where the Beijing Youth Daily proclaimed that “the management of the migrant population is out of control.”3

  The phenomenon is also familiar to countries around the Mediterranean. According to Henry Boldrick, after World War II, rural migrants in Turkey headed toward the cities, building their own dwellings on government land. These spontaneous settlements, known as gecekondus, now house at least half of Turkey’s urban population. Although some gecekondus have been at least partly legalized and consequently have been able to gain some municipal services, the majority are still informal.4

  In the Philippines, the newspaper Business World called on the government “to stem the tide of humanity that is congesting our city to bursting point…. You see barong-barongs made of concrete and hollow blocks—and you begin to wonder. What is the government doing about the growing problem of homelessness, of squatters in our cities?”5

  In South Africa, some observers (including myself) believe the extralegal real estate sector is on the verge of its second major expansion. In 1998, Newsweek reported that “more and more [South African blacks] are filling the squatter camps and shantytowns that surround every South African city. Under apartheid, racial pass laws confined many blacks to rural areas. Now they travel freely—but hardly in comfort.”6 The Economist confirmed the trend: “Though anti-white political violence never really materialized, the end of racial segregation made it easier for poor blacks to wander into rich white areas.”7

  In Egypt, intellectuals and technocrats seem to have been aware of the issue for some time. According to one recent report, between 1947 and 1989 “Egypt’s total urban population has…increased…from 6.2 million to 23.46 million.”8 Figures compiled by Gerard Barthelemy show that the population in the metropolitan area of Port-au-Prince, Haiti, rose from 140,000 in 1950 to 1,550,000 in 1988 and is now approaching 2 million. Barthelemy estimates that about two-thirds of these people live in shantytowns, or what the Haitians call bidonvilles.9

  In Mexico, the private sector has become increasingly conscious of the extralegal phenomenon and actively involved in doing something about it. According to one news report:

  A 1987 study by the Center for Private Sector Economic Studies (CPSES) estimated that the extral
egal informal sector generated economic activity worth between 28% and 39% of the official Mexican GDP, and a 1993 study…put the number of people in the “non-registered informal sector” at 8 million out of a total workforce of 23 million…. “For every formal business, there are two informal businesses,” says Antonio Montiel Guerrero, president of the Mexico City Small Business Chamber of Commerce (CACOPE), a group representing 167,000 small, registered formal businesses. “In the Federal District (Mexico City) there are about 350,000 small, informal businesses for a total population of roughly 8 million.” What that translates into for the whole 20-million-person Mexico City metropolitan area is anybody’s guess, especially when the unregulated and growing shantytowns are concentrated outside the central core of the city.10

  Extralegal zones in developing countries are characterized by modest homes cramped together on city perimeters, a myriad of workshops in their midst, armies of vendors hawking their wares on the streets, and countless crisscrossing minibus lines. All seem to have sprung out of nowhere. Steady streams of small crafts workers, tools under their arms, have expanded the range of activities carried out in the city. Ingenious local adaptations add to the production of essential goods and services, dramatically transforming certain areas of manufacturing, retail distribution, building, and transportation. The passive landscapes that once surrounded Third World cities have become the latest extensions of the metropolis, and cities modeled on the European style have yielded to a more noisy, local personality blended with drab imitations of suburban America’s commercial strip.

 

‹ Prev