Book Read Free

The Black Swan

Page 57

by Nassim Nicholas Taleb


  ———2010, “Beliefs, Decisions, and Probability,” in T. O’Connor and C. Sandis, eds., A Companion to the Philosophy of Action (Wiley-Blackwell).

  Taleb, N. N., and C. Tapiero, 2010a, “Too Big to Fail and the Fallacy of Large Institutions” (preprint, NYU-Poly).

  ———2010b, “The Risk Externalities of Too Big to Fail” (preprint, NYU-Poly).

  Tashman, Leonard J., 2000, “Out of Sample Tests of Forecasting Accuracy: An Analysis and Review.” International Journal of Forecasting 16(4): 437–450.

  Teigen, K. H., 1974, “Overestimation of Subjective Probabilities.” Scandinavian Journal of Psychology 15: 56–62.

  Terracciano, A., et al., 2005, “National Character Does Not Reflect Mean Personality Traits.” Science 310: 96.

  Tetlock, Philip E., 1999, “Theory-Driven Reasoning About Plausible Pasts and Probable Futures in World Politics: Are We Prisoners of Our Preconceptions?” American Journal of Political Science 43(2): 335–366.

  ———, 2005, “Expert Political Judgment: How Good Is It? How Can We Know?” Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

  Thaler, Richard, 1985, “Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice.” Marketing Science 4(3): 199–214.

  Thom, René, 1980, Paraboles et catastrophes. Paris: Champs Flammarion.

  ———, 1993, Prédire n’est pas expliquer. Paris: Champs Flammarion.

  Thorley, 1999, “Investor Overconfidence and Trading Volume.” Working Paper, Santa Clara University.

  Tilly, Charles, 2006, Why? What Happens When People Give Reasons and Why. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

  Tinbergen, N., 1963, “On Aims and Methods in Ethology.” Zeitschrift fur Tierpsychologie 20: 410–433.

  ———, 1968, “On War and Peace in Animals and Man: An Ethologist’s Approach to the Biology of Aggression.” Science 160: 1411–1418.

  Tobin, James, 1958, “Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk.” Review of Economic Studies 67: 65–86.

  Triantis, Alexander J., and James E. Hodder, 1990, “Valuing Flexibility as a Complex Option.” Journal of Finance 45(2): 549–564.

  Trivers, Robert, 2002, Natural Selection and Social Theory: Selected Papers of Robert Trivers. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  Turner, Mark, 1996, The Literary Mind. New York: Oxford University Press.

  Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman, 1971, “Belief in the Law of Small Numbers.” Psychology Bulletin 76(2): 105–110.

  ———, 1973, “Availability: A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability.” Cognitive Psychology 5: 207–232.

  ———, 1974, “Judgement Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases.” Science 185: 1124–1131.

  ———, 1982, “Evidential Impact of Base-Rates.” In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, and A. Tversky, eds., Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  ———, 1983, “Extensional Versus Intuitive Reasoning: The Conjunction Fallacy in Probability Judgment.” Psychological Review 90: 293–315.

  ———, 1992, “Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5: 297–323.

  Tversky, A., and D. J. Koehler, 1994, “Support Theory: A Nonextensional Representation of Subjective Probability.” Psychological Review 101: 547–567.

  Tyszka, T., and P. Zielonka, 2002, “Expert Judgments: Financial Analysts Versus Weather Forecasters.” Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets 3(3): 152–160.

  Uglow, Jenny, 2003, The Lunar Men: Five Friends Whose Curiosity Changed the World. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.

  Vale, Nilton Bezerra do, José Delfino, and Lúcio Flávio Bezerra do Vale, 2005, “Serendipity in Medicine and Anesthesiology.” Revista Brasileira de Anestesiologia 55(2): 224–249.

  van Tongeren, Paul, 2002, “Nietzsche’s Greek Measure.” Journal of Nietzsche Studies 24: 5.

  Vandenbroucke, J. P., 1996, “Evidence-Based Medicine and ‘Medicine d’Observation,’” Journal of Clinical Epidemiology, 49(12): 1335–1338.

  Varela, Francisco J., 1988, Invitation aux sciences cognitives. Paris: Champs Flammarion.

  Varian, Hal R., 1989, “Differences of Opinion in Financial Markets.” In Courtenay C. Stone, ed., Financial Risk: Theory, Evidence and Implications: Proceedings of the Eleventh Annual Economic Policy Conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Boston: Kitiwer Academic Publishers.

  Véhel, Jacques Lévy, and Christian Walter, 2002, Les marchés fractals: Efficience, ruptures, et tendances sur les marchés financiers. Paris: PUF.

  Veyne, Paul, 1971, Comment on écrit l’histoire. Paris: Éditions du Seuil.

  ———, 2005, L’Empire gréco-romain. Paris: Éditions du Seuil.

  Vogelstein, Bert, David Lane, and Arnold J. Levine, 2000, “Surfing the P53 Network.” Nature 408: 307–310.

  Voit, Johannes, 2001, The Statistical Mechanics of Financial Markets. Heidelberg: Springer.

  von Mises, R., 1928, Wahrscheinlichkeit, Statistik und Wahrheit. Berlin: Springer. Translated and reprinted as Probability, Statistics, and Truth. New York: Dover, 1957.

  von Plato, Jan, 1994, Creating Modern Probability. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  von Winterfeldt, D., and W. Edwards, 1986, Decision Analysis and Behavioral Research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  Wagenaar, Willern, and Gideon B. Keren, 1985, “Calibration of Probability Assessments by Professional Blackjack Dealers, Statistical Experts, and Lay People.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 36: 406–416.

  ———, 1986, “Does the Expert Know? The Reliability of Predictions and Confidence Ratings of Experts.” In Erik Hollnagel, Giuseppe Mancini, and David D. Woods, Intelligent Design Support in Process Environments. Berlin: Springer.

  Waller, John, 2002, Fabulous Science: Fact and Fiction in the History of Scientific Discovery. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  Wallerstein, Immanuel, 1999, “Braudel and Interscience: A Preacher to Empty Pews?” Paper presented at the 5th Journées Braudeliennes, Binghamton University, Binghamton, N.Y.

  Wallsten, T. S., D. V. Budescu, I. Erev, and A. Diederich, 1997, “Evaluating and Combining Subjective Probability Estimates.” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 10: 243–268.

  Wason, P. C., 1960, “On the Failure to Eliminate Hypotheses in a Conceptual Task.” Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology 12: 129–140.

  Watts, D. J., 2003, Six Degrees: The Science of a Connected Age. New York: W. W. Norton and Company.

  Watts, D. J., and S. H. Strogatz, 1998, “Collective Dynamics of ‘Small-world’ Networks.” Nature 393: 440–442

  Watts, Duncan, 2002, “A Simple Model of Global Cascades on Random Networks.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 99(9): 5766–5771.

  Wegner, Daniel M., 2002, The Illusion of Conscious Will. Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press.

  Weinberg, Steven, 2001, “Facing Up: Science and Its Cultural Adversaries.” Working Paper, Harvard University.

  Weintraub, Roy E., 2002, How Economics Became a Mathematical Science, Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.

  Wells, G. L., and Harvey, J. H., 1977, “Do People Use Consensus Information in Making Causal Attributions?” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35: 279–293.

  Weron, R., 2001, “Levy-Stable Distributions Revisited: Tail Index > 2 Does Not Exclude the Levy- Stable Regime.” International Journal of Modern Physics 12(2): 209–223.

  Wheatcroft, Andrew, 2003, Infidels: A History of Conflict Between Christendom and Islam. New York: Random House.

  White, John, 1982, Rejection. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.

  Whitehead, Alfred North, 1925, Science and the Modern World. New York: The Free Press.

  Williams, Mark A., Simon A. Moss, John L. Bradshaw, and Nicole J. Rinehart, 2002, “Brief Report: Random Number Generation in Autism.” Journal of Autism and Developmental Disorders 32(1): 43–47.

  Williams, Robert J., and Dennis
Connolly, 2006, “Does Learning About the Mathematics of Gambling Change Gambling Behavior?” Psychology of Addictive Behaviors 20(1): 62–68.

  Willinger, W., D. Alderson, J. C. Doyle, and L. Li, 2004, “A Pragmatic Approach to Dealing with High Variability Measurements.” Proceedings of the ACM SIGCOMM Internet Measurement Conference, Taormina, Sicily, October 25–27, 2004.

  Wilson, Edward O., 2000, Sociobiology: The New Synthesis. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

  ———, 2002, The Future of Life. New York: Knopf.

  Wilson, T. D., J. Meyers, and D. Gilbert, 2001, “Lessons from the Past: Do People Learn from Experience That Emotional Reactions Are Short Lived?” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 29: 1421–1432.

  Wilson, T. D., D. T. Gilbert, and D. B. Centerbar, 2003, “Making Sense: The Causes of Emotional Evanescence.” In I. Brocas and J. Carillo, eds., 2003.

  Wilson, T. D., D. B. Centerbar, D. A. Kermer, and D. T. Gilbert, 2005, “The Pleasures of Uncertainty: Prolonging Positive Moods in Ways People Do Not Anticipate.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 88(1): 5–21.

  Wilson, Timothy D., 2002, Strangers to Ourselves: Discovering the Adaptive Unconscious. Cambridge, Mass.: The Belknap Press of Harvard University.

  Winston, Robert, 2002, Human Instinct: How Our Primeval Impulses Shape Our Lives. London: Bantam Press.

  Wolford, George, Michael B. Miller, and Michael Gazzaniga, 2000, “The Left Hemisphere’s Role in Hypothesis Formation.” Journal of Neuroscience 20: 1–4.

  Wood, Michael, 2003, The Road to Delphi. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.

  Wrangham, R., 1999, “Is Military Incompetence Adaptive?” Evolution and Human Behavior 20: 3–12.

  Yates, J. F., 1990, Judgment and Decision Making. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

  Yates, J. F., J. Lee, and H. Shinotsuka, 1996, “Beliefs About Overconfidence, Including Its Cross- National Variation.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65: 138–147.

  Yates, J. F., J.-W. Lee, H. Shinotsuka, and W. R. Sieck, 1998, “Oppositional Deliberation: Toward Explaining Overconfidence and Its Cross-cultural Variations.” Paper presented at the meeting of the Psychonomics Society, Dallas, Tex.

  Yule, G., 1925, “A Mathematical Theory of Evolution, Based on the Conclusions of Dr. J. C. Willis, F. R. S.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, Series B 213: 21–87.

  Yule, G. U., 1944, Statistical Study of Literary Vocabulary. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  Zacks, R. T., L. Hasher, and H. Sanft, 1982, “Automatic Encoding of Event Frequency: Further Findings.” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 8: 106–116.

  Zajdenweber, Daniel, 2000, L’économie des extrèmes. Paris: Flammarion.

  Zajonc, R. B., 1980, “Feeling and Thinking: Preferences Need No Inferences.” American Psychologist 35: 151–175.

  ———, 1984, “On the Primacy of Affect.” American Psychologist 39: 117–123.

  Zeki, Semir, 1999, Inner Vision. London: Oxford University Press.

  Zimmer, A. C., 1983, “Verbal vs. Numerical Processing by Subjective Probabilities.” In R. W. Scholz, ed., Decision Making Under Uncertainty. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

  Zipf, George Kingsley, 1932, Selective Studies and the Principle of Relative Frequency in Language. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

  ———, 1949, Human Behavior and the Principle of Least Effort. Cambridge, Mass.: Addison- Wesley.

  Zitzewitz, Eric, 2001, “Measuring Herding and Exaggeration by Equity Analysts and Other Opinion Sellers.” Working Paper, Stanford University.

  Zuckerman, H., 1977, Scientific Elite. New York: The Free Press.

  ———, 1998, “Accumulation of Advantage and Disadvantage: The Theory and Its Intellectual Biography.” In C. Mongardini and S. Tabboni, eds., Robert K. Merton and Contemporary Sociology. New York: Transaction Publishers.

  Zweig, Stefan, 1960, Montaigne. Paris: Press Universitaires de France.

  ACKNOWLEDGMENTS FOR THE FIRST EDITION

  I derived an unexpected amount of enjoyment in writing this book—in fact, it just wrote itself—and I want the reader to experience the same. I would like to thank the following friends.

  My friend and adviser Rolf Dobelli, the novelist, entrepreneur, and voracious reader, kept up with the various versions of this text. I also built up a large debt toward Peter Bevelin, an erudite and pure “thinking doer” with extreme curiosity who spends his waking hours chasing ideas and spotting the papers I am usually looking for; he scrutinized the text. Yechezkel Zilber, a Jerusalem-based idea-starved autodidact who sees the world ab ovo, from the egg, asked very tough questions, to the point of making me ashamed of the formal education I received and uncomfortable for not being a true autodidact like him—it is thanks to no-nonsense people that I am grounding my Black Swan idea in academic libertarianism. The scholar Philip Tetlock, who knows more about prediction than anyone since the Delphic times, went through the manuscript and scrutinized my arguments. Phil is so valuable and thorough that he was even more informational with the absence of comments than he was with his comments. I owe a big debt to Danny Kahneman who, in addition to the long conversations on my topics of human nature (and noting with horror that I remembered almost every comment), put me in contact with Phil Tetlock. I thank Maya Bar Hillel for inviting me to address the Society of Judgment and Decision Making at their annual meeting in Toronto in No vember 2005—thanks to the generosity of the researchers there, and the stimulating discussions, I came back having taken away far more than I gave. Robert Shiller asked me to purge some “irreverent” comments, but the fact that he criticized the aggressiveness of the delivery, but not the content, was quite informational. Mariagiovanna Muso was the first to become conscious of the Black Swan effect on the arts and sent me along the right lines of research in sociology and anthropology. I had long discussions with the literary scholar Mihai Spariosu on Plato, Balzac, ecological intelligence, and cafés in Bucharest. Didier Sornette, always a phone call away, kept e-mailing me papers on various unadvertised, but highly relevant, subjects in statistical physics. Jean-Philippe Bouchaud offered a great deal of help on the problems associated with the statistics of large deviations. Michael Allen wrote a monograph for writers looking to get published, based on the ideas of Chapter 8—I subsequently rewrote Chapter 8 through the eyes of a writer looking at his lot in life. Mark Blyth was always helpful as a sounding board, reader, and adviser. My friends at the DoD, Andy Marshall and Andrew Mays, supplied me with ideas and questions. Paul Solman, a voracious mind, went through the manuscript with severe scrutiny. I owe the term Extremistan to Chris Anderson, who found my earlier designation too bookish. Nigel Harvey guided me through the literature on forecasting.

  I plied the following scientists with questions: Terry Burnham, Robert Trivers, Robyn Dawes, Peter Ayton, Scott Atran, Dan Goldstein, Alexander Reisz, Art De Vany, Raphael Douady, Piotr Zielonka, Gur Huberman, Elkhonon Goldberg, and Dan Sperber. Ed Thorp, the true living owner of the “Black-Scholes formula” was helpful; I realized, speaking to him, that economists ignore intellectual productions outside their club—regardless how valuable. Lorenzo Perilli was extremely generous with his comments about Menodotus and helped correct a few errors. Duncan Watts allowed me to present the third part of this book at a Columbia University seminar in sociology and collect all manner of comments. David Cowan supplied the graph in the Poincaré discussion, making mine pale by comparison. I also benefited from James Montier’s wonderful brief pieces on human nature. Bruno Dupire, as always, provides the best walking conversations.

  It does not pay to be the loyal friend of a pushy author too close to his manuscript. Marie-Christine Riachi was given the thankless task of reading chapters in inverse order; I only gave her the incomplete pieces and, of those, only the ones (then) patently lacking in clarity. Jamil Baz received the full text every time but chose to read it backwards. Laurence Zur
iff read and commented on every chapter. Philip Halperin, who knows more about risk management than anyone (still) alive, offered wonderful comments and observations. Other victims: Cyrus Pirasteh, Bernard Oppetit, Pascal Boulard, Guy Riviere, Joelle Weiss, Didier Javice, Andreea Munteanu, Andrei Pokrovsky, Philippe Asseily, Farid Karkaby, George Nasr, Alina Stefan, George Martin, Stan Jonas, and Flavia Cymbalista. I also thank Linda Eckstein and Justin Fox (for the market graph), as well as Paul Kaju, Martin Pomp, and Lea Beresford.

  I received helpful comments from the voracious intellectual Paul Solman (who went through the manuscript with a microscope). I owe a lot to Phil Rosenczweig, Avishai Margalit, Peter Forbes, Michael Schrage, Driss Ben Brahim, Vinay Pande, Antony Van Couvering, Nicholas Vardy, Brian Hinchcliffe, Aaron Brown, Espen Haug, Neil Chriss, Zvika Afik, Shaiy Pilpel, Paul Kedrosky, Reid Bernstein, Claudia Schmid, Jay Leonard, Shellwyn Weston, Tony Glickman, Paul Johnson, Chidem Kurdas (and the NYU Austrian economists), Charles Babbitt, plus so many anonymous persons I have forgotten about* …

  Ralph Gomory and Jesse Ausubel of the Sloan Foundation run a research funding program called the Known, the Unknown, and the Unknowable. They offered their moral and financial help for the promotion of my ideas—I took the invaluable moral option. I also thank my business partners, coauthors, and intellectual associates: Espen Haug, Mark Spitznagel, Benoît Mandelbrot, Tom Witz, Paul Wilmott, Avital Pilpel, and Emanuel Derman. I also thank John Brockman and Katinka Matson for making this book possible, and Max Brockman for his comments on the draft. I thank Cindy, Sarah, and Alexander for their tolerance. In addition, Alexander helped with the graphs and Sarah worked on the bibliography. Mark Fandetti, Mark Horowitz, Bruce Waxman, Spiros Makridakis, Jack Schwagger, and Elie Ayache helped with the more technical typos. The readers Jonathan Skinner, Harry Thayer, and David Evans helped correct technical and factual mistakes. I thank Linda Eckstein and Justin Fox for suggesting to Mandelbrot and me the graph of the SP500.

  I tried to give my editor, Will Murphy, the impression of being an unbearably stubborn author, only to discover that I was fortunate that he was an equally stubborn editor (but good at hiding it). He protected me from the intrusions of the standardizing editors. They have an uncanny ability to inflict maximal damage by breaking the internal rhythm of one’s prose with the minimum of changes. Will M. is also the right kind of party animal. I was also flattered that Daniel Menaker took the time to edit my text. I also thank Janet Wygal and Steven Meyers. The staff at Random House was accommodating—but they never got used to my phone pranks (like my trying to pass for Bernard-Henri Lévy). One of the highlights of my writing career was a long lunch with William Goodlad, my editor at Penguin, and Stefan McGrath, the managing director of the group. I suddenly realized that I could not separate the storyteller in me from the scientific thinker; as a matter of fact, the story came first to my mind, rather than as an after-the-fact illustration of the concept.

 

‹ Prev